Social Europe

politics, economy and employment & labour

  • Themes
    • Strategic autonomy
    • War in Ukraine
    • European digital sphere
    • Recovery and resilience
  • Publications
    • Books
    • Dossiers
    • Occasional Papers
    • Research Essays
    • Brexit Paper Series
  • Podcast
  • Videos
  • Newsletter

Intellectual monopoly capitalism—challenge of our times

Cédric Durand and Cecilia Rikap 5th October 2021

Unregulated capitalism has always tended to monopoly. But Big Tech represents a challenge antitrust tools can’t tame.

patent,intellectual property,intellectual monopoly capitalism
Hayek recognised that treating knowledge as other than ‘a gratuity’ was patent nonsense (Chumakov Oleg / shutterstock.com)

Scientia potentia est—knowledge is power. The old adage has acquired a sinister connotation with the alarming dominance of Big Tech in the economy and society as a whole. Corporate Europe Observatory recently revealed that the sector is now by far the leading business lobbyist of European Union institutions.

But this is only the tip of the Iceberg of what the Italian economist Ugo Pagano calls ‘intellectual monopoly capitalism’. Knowledge, which should be a (non-rival, non-exclusive) public good, has been privately appropriated by top companies as capital: the share of intangible assets among S&P 500 corporations increased from 17 per cent in 1975 to 90 per cent in 2020.

For Pagano, the dramatic expansion of intellectual-property rights ‘involves the creation of a legal monopoly that can be potentially extended to the entire global economy’. His claim against a strict IP regime echoes the traditional position of economists treating knowledge as a gratuity. Friedrich Hayek, for example, contended:

The growth of knowledge is of such special importance because, while the material resources will always remain scarce and will have to be reserved for limited purposes, the uses of new knowledge (where we do not make them artificially scarce by patents of monopoly) are unrestricted. Knowledge, once achieved, becomes gratuitously available for the benefit of all.


Our job is keeping you informed!


Subscribe to our free newsletter and stay up to date with the latest Social Europe content. We will never send you spam and you can unsubscribe anytime.

Sign up here

Recent calls for a patent waiver on Covid-19 vaccines graphically illustrate this broader principle: general progress requires that knowledge accrued through the experiments of some members of society be freely gifted.

The concentration of economic power and benefits is however increasing, based on depriving others of access to knowledge. Legal monopoly is already very well advanced, with just 2,000 corporations owning 60 per cent of the patents simultaneously obtained at the world’s five leading patent offices.

In the digital arena, secrecy is also a prevailing form of knowledge privatisation. Only 15 per cent of artificial-intelligence papers disclose the code involved. Google’s DeepMind is among those organisations that usually do not.

Additional mechanisms

Three additional mechanisms escalate global intellectual monopolisation. The first is predation in corporate-scientific networks. This is particularly evident in the pharmaceutical industry, where companies rely extensively on the work of scholars and use public funding for their research, yet they alone capture the profits from commercial exploitation.

A recent example is Remdesivir, used to treat Covid-19. This drug was patented and sold at an exhorbitant price by Gilead, even though entirely based on university research funded by the US National Institutes of Health. The NIH is the most frequent external funding source declared in Pfizer, Novartis and Roche scientific publications. Similarly, Google, Amazon and Microsoft co-authored between 78 and 87 per cent of their scientific publications until 2019, mostly with universities, but only shared ownership of between 0.1 and 0.3 per cent of their patents with other organisations.

A second, self-reinforcing intellectual-monopoly mechanism is related to the harvesting of data, where not only privacy concerns are at issue. In many industries, as the former Siemens chief executive Joe Kaeser said, manufacturing and engineering data are ‘the holy grail of innovation’. Since deep-learning algorithms learn and improve by themselves as they process more data, data harvesting results in continuous technical improvement.

Deep learning significantly automates discoveries and expands the types of problem that can be addressed through big-data analysis. Companies mastering this technology and exclusively owning original data sources expand their intellectual monopoly at an accelerating speed. This is true in many sectors, from finance with BlackRock’s platform Aladdin to retail with Walmart’s aggressive push towards proprietary data-analytics capacities. Nonetheless, technology giants increasingly occupy a leading role.

In 2015 Amazon, Microsoft, Google and Alibaba held in their public clouds around 4.9 per cent of the data stored worldwide but by 2020 this proportion had already reached 22.8 per cent. In their clouds, these companies offer deep-learning algorithms as a service. This means that, even without direct access to clients, algorithms can learn from third-party data, expanding the firms’ intellectual monopolies and allowing them to jump into other industries, from healthcare to transport.


We need your support


Social Europe is an independent publisher and we believe in freely available content. For this model to be sustainable, however, we depend on the solidarity of our readers. Become a Social Europe member for less than 5 Euro per month and help us produce more articles, podcasts and videos. Thank you very much for your support!

Become a Social Europe Member

A third phenomenon is related to the expansion of global value chains. The corollary of the unbundling of productive activities allowed by information and communication technologies is a dramatically increased circulation of information and a related sophistication of information systems, hand in hand with a concentration of the capabilities to govern networks. Lead firms’ planning capacity ranges from defining the dimensions of each production step taking place in subordinate companies to the setting of norms, standards and behavioural patterns. Moreover, the uneven distribution of uses of intangible assets along different nodes of the chains allows firms specialised in knowledge-intensive segments to capture most of the gains from scale economies.

Apple’s ‘fabless’ (outsourcing of fabrication) model and its masterful control over supply chains is a case point. The firm abandoned factories in Colorado Springs and Sacramento in 1996 and 2004 respectively, becoming the most renowned factory-less goods producer in the world. Most of its manufacturing is performed by firms in China and elsewhere in the global south, while Apple built ‘a closed ecosystem where it exerts control over nearly every piece of the supply chain, from design to retail store’. Critical in this panopticon surveying a highly dispersed manufacturing process is the monopoly over intellectual capabilities which allows Apple to capture the lion’s share of the value produced in the chain.

Falling short

Increasing awareness of the economic, social and political risks associated with the rising concentration of corporate power led to a recent antitrust push, first in the EU and the United Kingdom, followed by the United States and latterly China. Such moves however fall short of the challenges raised by intellectual monopoly capitalism, which go beyond the Big Tech companies and encompass much more than conventional market concentration.

What is at stake is a concentration of the ability to understand, co-ordinate and transform social and economic processes. Intellectual monopoly concerns new collective capabilities which should not be harnessed to the profit motive but rather be mobilised to achieve shared social, ecological and psychological development goals. This requires a new generation of resolute, innovative and co-ordinated policies, along at least two main dimensions.

First, following the ‘do no harm’ principle, extensive algorithmic accountability should prevail. Addressing responsibility for algorithmic decision-making should move beyond privacy issues and the biases leading to discriminatory and inequitable outcomes. Since control over algorithms makes it possible to ‘model, anticipate and pre-emptively affect possible behaviours’ and these capabilities are subjected to powerful monopoly forces, public authorities must prevent corporate uses of big data that encourage detrimental behaviours, such as compulsory consumption, carbon-intensive activities or online bullying. To that end, large-scale algorithmic apparatuses should be submitted to annual mandatory auditing, with publication of the relevant results.

Secondly, the resolution of crises and the attainment of socially and ecologically desirable goals must not be curtailed by intellectual monopoly. Patents should be automatically and generously waived where the free circulation of knowledge can contribute to alleviating social, health or ecological hardships.

Furthermore, intellectual monopolies set science and technology agendas, as evidenced by Big Pharma. This results in innovation rates and directions that privilege profit-making over solving social, ecological and health crises. Global institutional efforts are required to set new research agendas suported by public funds. But this is not nearly enough.

In the midst of the pandemic, Google made temporarily available its community mobility reports, which helped to assess the impact of mobility restriction on the spread of the disease. It is shocking that general-interest data such as these are not available on a permanent basis. Given the ability to process knowledge and behavioural data has become a powerful governing tool, algorithms should be open-source and data of general interest publicly available in anonymised form. Only thus can relevant big-data arrangements be deployed to serve public policies and prevent the predation of value across the economic landscape.

The Chinese state is already moving in this direction in the financial sector. As part of the implementation of its social-credit system, the central bank called data collected by internet platforms a ‘public good’, which should be disclosed and regulated more closely. Aversion to the lack of democracy and pervasive state surveillance in China is no excuse for letting crucial resources for the co-ordination of social life end up as a private monopoly. Creating a digital commons comprising data, algorithms and digital infrastructure could tackle both surveillance and data-driven intellectual monopolies. It would be a potential avenue for a socialisation empowering public agencies and private socio-economic actors alike.

Moving in these directions would imply a U-turn from the proprietary ideology of the previous fin de siècle. But it would just be a fair return to society. After all, Big Tech data scientists acknowledge that ‘the algorithms aren’t magic; they simply share with you what other people have already discovered’.

knowledge,intellectual property,patent
Cédric Durand

Cédric Durand is an associate professor of economics at the University of Geneva and a member of the Centre d’économie Paris Nord. He is author of Techno-féodalisme: critique de l'économie numérique (La découverte / Zones, 2020) and Fictitious Capital: How Finance is Appropriating our Future (Verso, 2017).

Cecilia Rikap 1
Cecilia Rikap

Cecilia Rikap is a lecturer in international political economy (IPE) at the City University of London, a researcher at CONICET, Argentina’s research council, and associate researcher at COSTECH lab, Université de Technologie de Compiègne. She is author of Capitalism, Power and Innovation: Intellectual Monopoly Capitalism Uncovered (Routledge) and co-author of The Digital Innovation Race: Conceptualizing the Emerging New World Order (Palgrave).

You are here: Home / Politics / Intellectual monopoly capitalism—challenge of our times

Most Popular Posts

European civil war,iron curtain,NATO,Ukraine,Gorbachev The new European civil warGuido Montani
Visentini,ITUC,Qatar,Fight Impunity,50,000 Visentini, ‘Fight Impunity’, the ITUC and QatarFrank Hoffer
Russian soldiers' mothers,war,Ukraine The Ukraine war and Russian soldiers’ mothersJennifer Mathers and Natasha Danilova
IGU,documents,International Gas Union,lobby,lobbying,sustainable finance taxonomy,green gas,EU,COP ‘Gaslighting’ Europe on fossil fuelsFaye Holder
Schengen,Fortress Europe,Romania,Bulgaria Romania and Bulgaria stuck in EU’s second tierMagdalena Ulceluse

Most Recent Posts

HMPs,CMR,hazardous medicinal products,carcinogenic, mutagenic and reprotoxic,health workers Protecting health workers from hazardous productsIan Lindsley, Tony Musu and Adam Rogalewski
geopolitical,Europe Options for Europe’s ‘geopolitical’ futureJon Bloomfield
democracy,democratic Reviving democracy in a fragmented EuropeSusanne Wixforth and Kaoutar Haddouti
EU social agenda,social investment,social protection EU social agenda beyond 2024—no time to wasteFrank Vandenbroucke
pension reform,Germany,Lindner Pension reform in Germany—a market solution?Fabian Mushövel and Nicholas Barr

Other Social Europe Publications

front cover scaled Towards a social-democratic century?
Cover e1655225066994 National recovery and resilience plans
Untitled design The transatlantic relationship
Women Corona e1631700896969 500 Women and the coronavirus crisis
sere12 1 RE No. 12: Why No Economic Democracy in Sweden?

Eurofound advertisement

Eurofound webinar: Making telework work for everyone

Since 2020 more European workers and managers have enjoyed greater flexibility and autonomy in work and are reporting their preference for hybrid working. Also driven by technological developments and structural changes in employment, organisations are now integrating telework more permanently into their workplace.

To reflect on these shifts, on 6 December Eurofound researchers Oscar Vargas and John Hurley explored the challenges and opportunities of the surge in telework, as well as the overall growth of telework and teleworkable jobs in the EU and what this means for workers, managers, companies and policymakers.


WATCH THE WEBINAR HERE

Foundation for European Progressive Studies Advertisement

Discover the new FEPS Progressive Yearbook and what 2023 has in store for us!

The Progressive Yearbook focuses on transversal European issues that have left a mark on 2022, delivering insightful future-oriented analysis for the new year. It counts on renowned authors' contributions, including academics, politicians and analysts. This fourth edition is published in a time of war and, therefore, it mostly looks at the conflict itself, the actors involved and the implications for Europe.


DOWNLOAD HERE

Hans Böckler Stiftung Advertisement

The macroeconomic effects of re-applying the EU fiscal rules

Against the background of the European Commission's reform plans for the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP), this policy brief uses the macroeconometric multi-country model NiGEM to simulate the macroeconomic implications of the most relevant reform options from 2024 onwards. Next to a return to the existing and unreformed rules, the most prominent options include an expenditure rule linked to a debt anchor.

Our results for the euro area and its four biggest economies—France, Italy, Germany and Spain—indicate that returning to the rules of the SGP would lead to severe cuts in public spending, particularly if the SGP rules were interpreted as in the past. A more flexible interpretation would only somewhat ease the fiscal-adjustment burden. An expenditure rule along the lines of the European Fiscal Board would, however, not necessarily alleviate that burden in and of itself.

Our simulations show great care must be taken to specify the expenditure rule, such that fiscal consolidation is achieved in a growth-friendly way. Raising the debt ceiling to 90 per cent of gross domestic product and applying less demanding fiscal adjustments, as proposed by the IMK, would go a long way.


DOWNLOAD HERE

ILO advertisement

Global Wage Report 2022-23: The impact of inflation and COVID-19 on wages and purchasing power

The International Labour Organization's Global Wage Report is a key reference on wages and wage inequality for the academic community and policy-makers around the world.

This eighth edition of the report, The Impact of inflation and COVID-19 on wages and purchasing power, examines the evolution of real wages, giving a unique picture of wage trends globally and by region. The report includes evidence on how wages have evolved through the COVID-19 crisis as well as how the current inflationary context is biting into real wage growth in most regions of the world. The report shows that for the first time in the 21st century real wage growth has fallen to negative values while, at the same time, the gap between real productivity growth and real wage growth continues to widen.

The report analysis the evolution of the real total wage bill from 2019 to 2022 to show how its different components—employment, nominal wages and inflation—have changed during the COVID-19 crisis and, more recently, during the cost-of-living crisis. The decomposition of the total wage bill, and its evolution, is shown for all wage employees and distinguishes between women and men. The report also looks at changes in wage inequality and the gender pay gap to reveal how COVID-19 may have contributed to increasing income inequality in different regions of the world. Together, the empirical evidence in the report becomes the backbone of a policy discussion that could play a key role in a human-centred recovery from the different ongoing crises.


DOWNLOAD HERE

ETUI advertisement

Social policy in the European Union: state of play 2022

Since 2000, the annual Bilan social volume has been analysing the state of play of social policy in the European Union during the preceding year, the better to forecast developments in the new one. Co-produced by the European Social Observatory (OSE) and the European Trade Union Institute (ETUI), the new edition is no exception. In the context of multiple crises, the authors find that social policies gained in ambition in 2022. At the same time, the new EU economic framework, expected for 2023, should be made compatible with achieving the EU’s social and ‘green’ objectives. Finally, they raise the question whether the EU Social Imbalances Procedure and Open Strategic Autonomy paradigm could provide windows of opportunity to sustain the EU’s social ambition in the long run.


DOWNLOAD HERE

About Social Europe

Our Mission

Article Submission

Membership

Advertisements

Legal Disclosure

Privacy Policy

Copyright

Social Europe ISSN 2628-7641

Social Europe Archives

Search Social Europe

Themes Archive

Politics Archive

Economy Archive

Society Archive

Ecology Archive

Follow us

RSS Feed

Follow us on Facebook

Follow us on Twitter

Follow us on LinkedIn

Follow us on YouTube