Social Europe

  • EU Forward Project
  • YouTube
  • Podcast
  • Books
  • Newsletter
  • Membership

How Edmund Phelps Got It Wrong On Greek Austerity

Achim Truger 23rd September 2015

Achim Truger

Achim Truger

In the debate on the Greek crisis, no cliché was too tawdry to be used and no claim too stupid or false to be made by large sections of the media and politics. Time and again, we read or heard how the “lazy Greeks” or “bankrupt Greeks” really ought to start cutting spending now.

The fact that the Greek government has had to implement a brutal austerity policy over the years since 2010, with spending cuts and income increases exceeding 20% of GDP (depending on the type of measurement), was deliberately overlooked. It should be immediately clear that austerity is directly linked to the disastrous economic crisis in Greece just as it is directly linked to the crisis in the Euro area as a whole (see two recent IMK publications).

General Consensus: Austerity Policy Contributed Substantially To The Recession

IMF chief economist Olivier Blanchard conceded some time ago that fiscal multipliers, i.e. the negative effects of austerity, had been greatly underestimated. In the meantime, the prevailing view among international experts has become that the restrictive fiscal policy in crisis-hit European states – Greece in particular – has greatly contributed to the severity and duration of the recession there.

Edmund Phelps’ Opinion

This consensus was recently contradicted by no less a person than Edmund S. Phelps, the US winner of the Nobel Prize in Economics, concerning Greece of all countries. In an article for Project Syndicate entitled “What Greece Needs to Prosper” published on 6 August, Phelps contradicts the “demand school” (Phelps’s term) that claims that austerity policy in Greece led to a demand deficiency and thus an acute depression. His central argument is empirical. To quote:

But this claim misreads history and exaggerates the power of government spending. Much of the decline in employment in Greece occurred prior to the sharp cuts in spending between 2012 and 2014 – owing, no doubt, to sinking confidence in the government. Greek government spending per quarter climbed to a plateau of around €13.5 billion ($14.8 billion) in 2009-2012, before falling to roughly €9.6 billion in 2014-2015. Yet the number of job holders reached its high of 4.5 million in 2006-2009, and had fallen to 3.6 million by 2012.

If Phelps is right in his assertion, the broadly accepted explanation for the Greek crisis (that it was caused by restrictive economic policy) would be severely undermined. How could austerity have caused a crisis that (almost) reached its peak more than three years before the policy was adopted?

Clarification Required

This needs clarification; a look at the data works wonders (as it so often does). First of all, Figure 1 shows the development of employment, specifically the number of persons in civilian employment, according to the EU Commission’s Ameco database (as of May 2015), on an annualised average. The trend asserted by Phelps can be reproduced approximately: after a rise in the number of job holders to a little over 4.5m in 2008, the figure declined slightly in 2009 and then fell dramatically to below 3.8m by 2012.

Figure 1 also attempts to reconstruct Phelps’s claims regarding “government spending” as specified in the article. It rose to €13.5bn by 2010 and then levelled off at this plateau until 2012. From 2013 onwards, it began to plummet, until it reached just €9.6bn in the first quarter of 2015, as stated by Phelps (in a further paragraph). (See below for more information on the trend’s reconstruction.) If this corresponds to the facts, then the spending cuts would indeed have been enforced too late to serve as an explanation for the drop in employment which began in 2009.

1

Government Consumption And Government Spending Are Not The Same Thing

What does Phelps actually mean by “government spending”? He cannot mean government spending as per the European system of accounting, because that was still at €88.4bn in 2014 according to Ameco. Even if that were artificially divided up into quarters in order to adopt the quarterly representation used by Phelps, it would result in €22.1bn or more than double the amount asserted by Phelps of almost €10bn.

The use of quarterly data indicates that Phelps did not in fact use the whole of government spending as a basis, but rather government consumption, i.e. state purchases of goods and services, which is usually published in the form of quarterly figures. Indeed, Eurostat (dated 20 August 2015) states real government consumption, neither seasonally adjusted nor working day adjusted, (reference year: 2010) for the first quarter of 2015 was €9.6bn for Greece — the exact figure quoted by Phelps.

But using government consumption, which makes up less than half of total government spending, already greatly limits the validity of Phelps’ analysis. Government consumption does not include government investments, subsidies and – most significantly – monetary social benefits, for example, unemployment benefit and pensions. Therefore, with his data, Phelps most certainly cannot prove that government spending in Greece was only cut significantly after 2012. Ultimately, extensive cuts to spending not included in government consumption could have been made much earlier. Even if they weren’t, substantial tax and duty rises could have triggered a drop in demand.

The Explanation: Incorrect Data!

But even if Phelps’s analysis only applied to government consumption (a mention of this would have been useful!), it would still help to shatter the prevailing explanation for the crisis: if almost half of government spending until 2012 was not subject to any real cuts, the degree of austerity may have been much smaller than previously assumed. This would also correspond to prevailing preconceptions: the Greeks have not questioned their government consumption, i.e. their “inefficient, inflated” public employment sector for a long time and may therefore have “delayed the necessary reforms for much too long”.

2In fact, the problem is that Phelps’s analysis is quite simply wrong: his portrayal of the development of government consumption, as reproduced in Figure 1, does not correspond to reality — or to quote Phelps, “misreads history”!

Therefore, Figure 2 shows the actual and annual average data for real government consumption (neither seasonally adjusted nor working day adjusted) and compares it with the reconstructed values from Figure 1, which Phelps asserted in his commentary (Eurostat, dated 20 August). This shows that real government consumption suffered a small drop as early as 2008, recovered in 2009, and then plummeted in 2010 – around three years earlier than claimed by Phelps.

The Correlation Between Government Consumption And Employment Is Clear

As is generally known, the crisis in Greece and the employment crash started three years earlier. Figure 3 also shows that there is an extremely strong correlation between the development of actual government consumption (in real terms) and the employment figures. From 2010 to 2013, the fall in employment ran parallel to the cuts in government consumption – if the latter is represented correctly.

3How could this data error have arisen? Only Edmund Phelps himself can answer that, but it appears that the time axis slipped by about three years or 12 quarters in the relevant period until 2012 (see Figure 2). When reconstructing the data in Figure 1, I moved the time axis by exactly three years for that reason, so that the values for 2003 correspond to those of 2000 in reality. In addition, I had to raise the plateau a little, as the annual average values actually remained below €13bn rather than rise to €13.5bn.

Another factor supporting the theory that moving the time axis was the cause of the confusion is that Phelps wrote: “€9.6bn in the first quarter of this year is, in fact, higher than it was as recently as 2003.” In reality, spending in 2003 was still over €10bn. You have to go back three years to 2000 to find annual average values that are below €9.6bn.

Whatever the reason, Edmund Phelps’ denial of austerity in Greece is simply wrong. Therefore the history of austerity policy and its impact in Greece does not have to be reinterpreted let alone rewritten.

This article was published in German for the first time in a slightly different version on the Arbeit & Wirtschaft blog on 3 September after a German-language commentary by Edmund Phelps was published in Handelsblatt on 20 August 2015.

Achim Truger

Achim Truger is Professor of Economics, particularly Macroeconomics and Economic Policy, at the Berlin School of Economics and Law and senior research fellow at the Macroeconomic Policy Institute (IMK) at Hans Böckler Foundation in Düsseldorf, Germany. He obtained his Doctorate in Economics at the University of Cologne, Germany, in 1997 where he was a Lecturer in Public Economics and an economist at the FiFo Institute for Public Economics until 1999. Until March 2012 he was a senior economist responsible for public finance and tax policy at the Macroeconomic Policy Institute (IMK) at Hans Böckler Foundation in Düsseldorf, Germany. He has served as an economic advisor to governments, parliaments, political parties, trade unions and NGOs on the international, national as well as regional level.

Harvard University Press Advertisement

Social Europe Ad - Promoting European social policies

We need your help.

Support Social Europe for less than €5 per month and help keep our content freely accessible to everyone. Your support empowers independent publishing and drives the conversations that matter. Thank you very much!

Social Europe Membership

Click here to become a member

Most Recent Articles

09d21a9 The Future of Social Democracy: How the German SPD can Win AgainHenning Meyer
u42198346 How Trump’s Tariff Regime Fuels Global OligarchyGabriel Zucman
u421983462 041df6feef0a 3 Universities Under Siege: A Global Reckoning for Higher EducationManuel Muñiz
u4219836ab582 af42 4743 a271 a4f423d1926d 0 How Trade Unions Can Champion Solidarity in Europe’s Migration DebateNeva Löw
u421983467298feb62884 0 The Weak Strongman: How Trump’s Presidency Emboldens America’s EnemiesTimothy Snyder

Most Popular Articles

u4219834647f 0894ae7ca865 3 Europe’s Businesses Face a Quiet Takeover as US Investors CapitaliseTej Gonza and Timothée Duverger
u4219834674930082ba55 0 Portugal’s Political Earthquake: Centrist Grip Crumbles, Right AscendsEmanuel Ferreira
u421983467e58be8 81f2 4326 80f2 d452cfe9031e 1 “The Universities Are the Enemy”: Why Europe Must Act NowBartosz Rydliński
u42198346761805ea24 2 Trump’s ‘Golden Era’ Fades as European Allies Face Harsh New RealityFerenc Németh and Peter Kreko
startupsgovernment e1744799195663 Governments Are Not StartupsMariana Mazzucato
u421986cbef 2549 4e0c b6c4 b5bb01362b52 0 American SuicideJoschka Fischer
u42198346769d6584 1580 41fe 8c7d 3b9398aa5ec5 1 Why Trump Keeps Winning: The Truth No One AdmitsBo Rothstein
u421983467 a350a084 b098 4970 9834 739dc11b73a5 1 America Is About to Become the Next BrexitJ Bradford DeLong
u4219834676ba1b3a2 b4e1 4c79 960b 6770c60533fa 1 The End of the ‘West’ and Europe’s FutureGuillaume Duval
u421983462e c2ec 4dd2 90a4 b9cfb6856465 1 The Transatlantic Alliance Is Dying—What Comes Next for Europe?Frank Hoffer

S&D Group in the European Parliament advertisement

Cohesion Policy

S&D Position Paper on Cohesion Policy post-2027: a resilient future for European territorial equity”,

Cohesion Policy aims to promote harmonious development and reduce economic, social and territorial disparities between the regions of the Union, and the backwardness of the least favoured regions with a particular focus on rural areas, areas affected by industrial transition and regions suffering from severe and permanent natural or demographic handicaps, such as outermost regions, regions with very low population density, islands, cross-border and mountain regions.

READ THE FULL POSITION PAPER HERE

ETUI advertisement

HESA Magazine Cover

What kind of impact is artificial intelligence (AI) having, or likely to have, on the way we work and the conditions we work under? Discover the latest issue of HesaMag, the ETUI’s health and safety magazine, which considers this question from many angles.

DOWNLOAD HERE

Eurofound advertisement

Ageing workforce
How are minimum wage levels changing in Europe?

In a new Eurofound Talks podcast episode, host Mary McCaughey speaks with Eurofound expert Carlos Vacas Soriano about recent changes to minimum wages in Europe and their implications.

Listeners can delve into the intricacies of Europe's minimum wage dynamics and the driving factors behind these shifts. The conversation also highlights the broader effects of minimum wage changes on income inequality and gender equality.

Listen to the episode for free. Also make sure to subscribe to Eurofound Talks so you don’t miss an episode!

LISTEN NOW

Foundation for European Progressive Studies Advertisement

Spring Issues

The Spring issue of The Progressive Post is out!


Since President Trump’s inauguration, the US – hitherto the cornerstone of Western security – is destabilising the world order it helped to build. The US security umbrella is apparently closing on Europe, Ukraine finds itself less and less protected, and the traditional defender of free trade is now shutting the door to foreign goods, sending stock markets on a rollercoaster. How will the European Union respond to this dramatic landscape change? .


Among this issue’s highlights, we discuss European defence strategies, assess how the US president's recent announcements will impact international trade and explore the risks  and opportunities that algorithms pose for workers.


READ THE MAGAZINE

Hans Böckler Stiftung Advertisement

WSI Report

WSI Minimum Wage Report 2025

The trend towards significant nominal minimum wage increases is continuing this year. In view of falling inflation rates, this translates into a sizeable increase in purchasing power for minimum wage earners in most European countries. The background to this is the implementation of the European Minimum Wage Directive, which has led to a reorientation of minimum wage policy in many countries and is thus boosting the dynamics of minimum wages. Most EU countries are now following the reference values for adequate minimum wages enshrined in the directive, which are 60% of the median wage or 50 % of the average wage. However, for Germany, a structural increase is still necessary to make progress towards an adequate minimum wage.

DOWNLOAD HERE

Social Europe

Our Mission

Team

Article Submission

Advertisements

Membership

Social Europe Archives

Themes Archive

Politics Archive

Economy Archive

Society Archive

Ecology Archive

Miscellaneous

RSS Feed

Legal Disclosure

Privacy Policy

Copyright

Social Europe ISSN 2628-7641