Social Europe

politics, economy and employment & labour

  • Themes
    • Global cities
    • Strategic autonomy
    • War in Ukraine
    • European digital sphere
    • Recovery and resilience
  • Publications
    • Books
    • Dossiers
    • Occasional Papers
    • Research Essays
    • Brexit Paper Series
  • Podcast
  • Videos
  • Newsletter
  • Membership

The Case For An Investment State

David Stoesz 21st June 2017

David Stoesz

David Stoesz

The case for an Investment State rests with three propositions: The first is the diminishing credibility of the Welfare State. Flourishing mid-20th century, it has struggled politically as a result of economic inequality, capital flight, bureaucratic inertia, damage to citizens, and the proliferation of subprime vendors. In response to the global financial crisis and the European debt crisis, government fiscal stimulus has been tepid at best. The second proposition is increasing, and occasionally virulent nationalism, fueled by working- and middle-class anxiety. Brexit, the Trump presidency, and insurgent populism threaten the solidarity premise of the Welfare State. Immigration has fueled xenophobia, resulting in heightened border security, signaling a closing of the post-1945 open societies of Europe. The third proposition is the fiscal exhaustion of the state. While social expenditure varies by nation, new challenges represented by working mothers, dislocated immigrants, a consolidated low-paying, non-unionised services sector, a growing precariat, and irreversible globalization put additional pressure on government—all this and the retirement of the Baby Boomers has yet to be addressed. Debt has limited Keynesian options, since national budgets are steeped in red ink, a problem compounded by the reluctance of governments to raise taxes. Fiscally, the Welfare State has run aground.

Constrained by neoliberal policies since the 1980s, European welfare scholars have explored social investment, but the logic of the Welfare State precludes a robust investment strategy. Fiscal resources of the state are already committed to politically powerful elders who demand pensions and healthcare, leaving governments to offer only token support to children, employed mothers, and workers needing to upgrade their skills. Insofar as the Welfare State is predicated on government revenues, the result is generational conflict, a zero-sum game pitting seniors against future generations. The inability of social theorists to square the social policy circle is due to the Welfare State’s paradigmatic dependence on the state.

A pivot toward capital would alleviate pressure on a sclerotic Welfare State by accessing private resources to address future demands, hence an Investment State.

Historically, the social infrastructure of developed nations has often relied on the private sector. Prior to the inception of the Welfare State, secular and sectarian organizations, such as Toynbee Hall in London and Hull House in Chicago, addressed the plight of immigrants dislocated by industrialization. Contemporaneous charitable foundations, often named after their benefactors—Andrew Carnegie, Henry Ford, Russell Sage—funded projects that government was unwilling or unable to mount. After World War II, companies lured desirable employees with benefit packages, which were also included in union collective bargaining agreements: “welfare capitalism.” During the final decades of the 20th century, corporations included social responsibility as an organizational objective, most recently expanded through the inception of “b-corporations,” or benefit corporations, which have social missions but pay taxes, now established in several countries.

An innovative model for social policy integrates behavioral economics, asset building, and impact investing to renew the social contract between citizens and government. European Union Development Accounts (EUDAs) demonstrate how private capital can be put to public purpose.


Become part of our Community of Thought Leaders


Get fresh perspectives delivered straight to your inbox. Sign up for our newsletter to receive thought-provoking opinion articles and expert analysis on the most pressing political, economic and social issues of our time. Join our community of engaged readers and be a part of the conversation.

Sign up here

  • The default for a EUDA would have workers save 5 percent of wages, increased to 10 percent at worker discretion, automatically diverted to an incentivized plan, unless they opt out.
  • The choice architecture matches worker savings for dedicated purposes: finishing vocational school or college, starting a business, or purchasing a first-time home. EUDAs would be progressive with savings matched according to worker attributes, so that Roma accounts, for example, would be matched 3:1, the poor 2:1, and other workers 1:1. EUDAs would be universal, tax exempt, and heritable.
  • The economic development factor is significant insofar as prior to withdrawal for dedicated purposes, EUDAs would be held in local financial institutions, providing capital for economic development projects.
  • The financing of EUDAs would be through Social Impact Bonds (SIBs).

Conceived by the Young Foundation in Britain, an SIB is a contract arranged by a third party intermediary, obligating government to pay principle plus interest to private investors provided that predetermined outcomes – cost-effective, constructive ones such as lower recidivism by offenders (see more here) – are delivered by service providers. An SIB strategy is innovative insofar as payment is contingent on delivering constructive, cost-effective outcomes. The role of government is limited to authorizing, evaluating, and paying on SIBs once outcomes are delivered.

Is there sufficient capital for EUDAs? Evidence suggests that certain investors, such as private foundations, socially oriented funds, and progressive individuals, are quite willing to put their capital to work in projects of modest scale. By 2017 over 60 SIBs have been launched in 15 countries, representing more than $200 million. The Ford Foundation in the U.S. has committed $1 billion toward impact investing. A subsidiary of the World Bank Group, the International Finance Corporation, issued a $500 million sustainability bond for “women-owned enterprises and low-income communities in emerging markets,” which was oversubscribed. A portion of a massive and untapped reservoir of capital, the “corporate savings glut,” could be diverted to public benefit through social investing. For 2013, gross savings minus gross investment for non-financial corporations in the US amounted to 3 percent of GDP, or $489 billion, while that of Japan was 6 percent, with Canada and Germany a bit more than 1 percent; cash and short-term investments held by just three companies, Google, Microsoft, and Apple, totaled $305 billion.

An Investment State thus poses new opportunities to address future social challenges. By accessing private capital, government can be a catalyst for a new generation of social programs that deliver predetermined outcomes. By investing in human capital and accelerating upward mobility, an Investment State can defuse pernicious populism while capitalizing social programs.

David Stoesz

David Stoesz, PhD, is Fulbright Distinguished Chair in Applied Public Policy at Carnegie Mellon University-Australia and Flinders University. In 2014 he was Fulbright Distinguished Chair in Social Policy at the University of Birmingham, UK. His books, published by Oxford University Press, include Quixote's Ghost: The Right, the Liberati, and the Future of Social Policy; The Dynamic Welfare State; Pandora's Dilemma: Theories of Social Welfare for the 21st Century and The Investment State: Charting the Future of Social Policy.

You are here: Home / Economy / The Case For An Investment State

Most Popular Posts

Belarus,Lithuania A tale of two countries: Belarus and LithuaniaThorvaldur Gylfason and Eduard Hochreiter
dissent,social critique,identity,politics,gender Delegitimising social critique and dissent on the leftEszter Kováts
retirement,Finland,ageing,pension,reform Late retirement: possible for many, not for allKati Kuitto
Credit Suisse,CS,UBS,regulation The failure of Credit Suisse—not just a one-offPeter Bofinger
Europe,transition,climate For a just and democratic climate transitionJulia Cagé, Lucas Chancel, Anne-Laure Delatte and 8 more

Most Recent Posts

work,labour market,pandemic,hours,Gen Z How much work is enough?Anne-Marie Slaughter and Autumn McDonald
poverty,Porto,Social Forum When life gives you lemons, make anti-poverty strategiesEstrella Durá Ferrandis and Alba Huertas Ruiz
LGBT+ rigthts,same-sex couples,civil unions,ECHR Landmark European ruling on LGBT+ rightsNausica Palazzo
boredom,work Rust out: boredom at work can be harmfulValerie van Mulukom
Kılıçdaroğlu,Turkey,Erdoğan Turkey: does Kılıçdaroğlu have a path to victory?Halil Karaveli

Other Social Europe Publications

Bildschirmfoto 2023 05 08 um 21.36.25 RE No. 13: Failed Market Approaches to Long-Term Care
front cover scaled Towards a social-democratic century?
Cover e1655225066994 National recovery and resilience plans
Untitled design The transatlantic relationship
Women Corona e1631700896969 500 Women and the coronavirus crisis

ETUI advertisement

The four transitions and the missing one

Europe is at a crossroads, painfully navigating four transitions (green, digital, economic and geopolitical) at once but missing the transformative and ambitious social transition it needs. In other words, if the EU is to withstand the storm, we do not have the luxury of abstaining from reflecting on its social foundations, of which intermittent democratic discontent is only one expression. It is against this background that the ETUI/ETUC publishes its annual flagship publication Benchmarking Working Europe 2023, with the support of more than 70 graphs and a special contribution from two guest editors, Professors Kalypso Nikolaidïs and Albena Azmanova.


DOWNLOAD HERE

Eurofound advertisement

New Europe-wide survey on living and working conditions

Eurofound, in partnership with the European Training Foundation, has launched a new online survey to document living and working conditions in Europe and the evolving concerns of citizens, amid the cost-of-living crisis, the war in Ukraine and the broader post-Covid-19 context.

The survey is available in 33 languages and is open to everyone over the age of 16. It asks specific questions on perceptions of quality of life and quality of society, as well as working situation, housing and finances.

Add your voice and contribute to the research.


COMPLETE THE SURVEY HERE

Foundation for European Progressive Studies Advertisement

The spring issue of the Progressive Post magazine from FEPS is out!

The Special Coverage of this new edition is dedicated to Feminist Foreign Policy, to try to gauge its potential but also the risk that it could be perceived as another attempt by the west to impose its vision on the global south.

In this issue, we also look at the human cost of the war in Ukraine, analyse the increasing connection between the centre right and the far right, and explore the difficulties, particularly for women, of finding a good work-life balance and living good working lives.


DOWNLOAD HERE

Hans Böckler Stiftung Advertisement

The macroeconomic effects of re-applying the EU fiscal rules

Against the background of the European Commission's reform plans for the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP), this policy brief uses the macroeconometric multi-country model NiGEM to simulate the macroeconomic implications of the most relevant reform options from 2024 onwards. Next to a return to the existing and unreformed rules, the most prominent options include an expenditure rule linked to a debt anchor.

Our results for the euro area and its four biggest economies—France, Italy, Germany and Spain—indicate that returning to the rules of the SGP would lead to severe cuts in public spending, particularly if the SGP rules were interpreted as in the past. A more flexible interpretation would only somewhat ease the fiscal-adjustment burden. An expenditure rule along the lines of the European Fiscal Board would, however, not necessarily alleviate that burden in and of itself.

Our simulations show great care must be taken to specify the expenditure rule, such that fiscal consolidation is achieved in a growth-friendly way. Raising the debt ceiling to 90 per cent of gross domestic product and applying less demanding fiscal adjustments, as proposed by the IMK, would go a long way.


DOWNLOAD HERE

About Social Europe

Our Mission

Article Submission

Membership

Advertisements

Legal Disclosure

Privacy Policy

Copyright

Social Europe ISSN 2628-7641

Social Europe Archives

Search Social Europe

Themes Archive

Politics Archive

Economy Archive

Society Archive

Ecology Archive

Follow us

RSS Feed

Follow us on Facebook

Follow us on Twitter

Follow us on LinkedIn

Follow us on YouTube