Social Europe

politics, economy and employment & labour

  • Themes
    • Global cities
    • Strategic autonomy
    • War in Ukraine
    • European digital sphere
    • Recovery and resilience
  • Publications
    • Books
    • Dossiers
    • Occasional Papers
    • Research Essays
    • Brexit Paper Series
  • Podcast
  • Videos
  • Newsletter
  • Membership

Central-bank digital currencies: proceed with caution

Peter Bofinger 29th October 2019

Peter Bofinger argues that introducing central-bank digital currencies would need to be subject to very careful consideration.

digital currencies
Peter Bofinger

While Facebook’s Libra is confronted by ever stronger headwinds, a new competitor, the so-called central-bank digital currency (CBDC), is entering the arena of digital money. While this idea has been discussed by several central banks for some time now, it has been boosted by recent announcements by Chinese central bankers. On August 10th Mu Changchun, deputy chief of the payment and settlement division of the People’s Bank of China, said: ‘People’s Bank digital currency can now be said to be ready.’

Different types of CBDC have been mooted (see table). Account-based CBDCs would make it possible for private households and corporations to open an account with the central bank. This could be designed as an all-purpose account for anyone, with unlimited uses (retail CBDCs). But CBDCs could also be designed as a pure store of value, which would only allow transactions between the central-bank account and a designated traditional bank account. Such accounts could be organised as retail CBDCs but access could be restricted to large investors and providers of payments platforms (wholesale CBDCs).

Token-based CBDCs (‘digital cash’) are imagined as an alternative to cash for peer-to-peer transactions. They could be designed as prepaid cash cards issued by the central bank, without the user having an account with the central bank.

A typology of CBDCs

table 2

These CBDC variants challenge existing money, financial-assets and payments providers:


Become part of our Community of Thought Leaders


Get fresh perspectives delivered straight to your inbox. Sign up for our newsletter to receive thought-provoking opinion articles and expert analysis on the most pressing political, economic and social issues of our time. Join our community of engaged readers and be a part of the conversation.

Sign up here

  • Token-based CBDCs would compete above all with private providers of digital-payments products (such as credit-card companies, Paypal and Alipay).
  • All-purpose CBDCs would compete with traditional bank accounts.
  • Store-of value, account-based CBDCs would compete with time deposits of commercial banks but particularly with ‘safe assets’ and above all government bonds.

With the issuance of token-based CBDCs, but also with all-purpose CBDCs for anybody, central banks would compete with private suppliers of payments networks and commercial banks.

Such a change in the competitive environment could only be justified were a significant market failure to be identified. The Swedish Rijksbank argues: ‘If the state, via the central bank, does not have any payment services to offer as an alternative to the strongly concentrated private payment market, it may lead to a decline in competitiveness and a less stable payment system, as well as make it difficult for certain groups to make payments.’

Effective competition policy

But the solution to these problems is not necessarily that the central bank becomes a provider of retail-payments services. Rather, this calls for an effective competition policy and comprehensive supervision of payments providers. And one has to ask whether the central bank would be an adequate institution for screening, monitoring and supporting customers, as well as developing new retail-payment technologies.

In addition, all-purpose CBDCs for private households and companies could raise serious problems for the financial-intermediation mechanism. If bank customers decided to shift significant parts of their deposits to the central bank, the deposit base of commercial banks would be reduced. This gap would have to be filled by the central bank, which would in turn require sufficient eligible collateral on the part of the banks.

If such accounts were to gain in popularity, the central bank would increasingly find itself in a situation in which it would have to refinance private loans and decide, indirectly or directly, on the quality of private borrowers. In the end a ‘full money’ (or 100 per cent reserve) financial system could emerge, in which commercial banks would lose the ability to create credit independently. Contrary to its advocates, this would massively throttle or even eliminate a central driver of economic momentum.

Safe assets

While fully-fledged CBDCs for private households and firms would be associated with serious challenges and risks for the whole financial system, there are no obvious market failures which could warrant such innovation. This raises the question of whether the introduction of CBDCs should be limited to ‘store of value’ CBDCs (sov-CBDCs). Such central-bank balances could not be used for payments to third parties but only for transfer to one’s own account at a commercial bank.

With store-of-value CBDCs the central bank would not compete with payments providers. The competition with commercial banks would be limited to short-term time and saving deposits, without depriving banks of their liquid deposit base. Above all, such CBDCs would provide a safe asset, which in this form could not be created by private actors. Sov-CBDCs would be comparable to cash as they would provide a 100 per cent guarantee of nominal value, which cannot be guaranteed by bank accounts—according to the Bank Resolution and Recovery Directive, depositors with assets in excess of €100,000 must be bailed in if their bank gets into trouble—or government bonds.

The attractiveness of this asset would be largely determined by its rate of return. Treating it as a digital substitute for cash, a zero interest rate would be appropriate. In this case, the substitution processes from traditional bank deposits to CBDCs would be limited. In addition, a lower limit of €100,000 for sov-CBDCs could be justified, as bank customers with lower deposits are protected by national deposit-insurance schemes.


Support Progressive Ideas: Become a Social Europe Member!


Support independent publishing and progressive ideas by becoming a Social Europe member for less than 5 Euro per month. You can help us create more high-quality articles, podcasts and videos that challenge conventional thinking and foster a more informed and democratic society. Join us in our mission - your support makes all the difference!

Become a Social Europe Member

Overall, such CBDCs would increase the stock of ‘safe assets’ that are of great importance to the players in the financial markets. This is also not without risks, however, as the introduction of a new safe asset could be detrimental for countries with a poorer bond rating. Moreover, in periods of crisis such CBDCs could lead to digital bank-runs, which would further destabilise the system.

Synthetic CBDCs

The narrowest version of CBDCs comprise store-of-value CBDCs restricted to providers of payments services as a collateral for their depositors (‘stable coins’). The designers of Libra plan to use bank deposits and government bonds as collateral. But, as indicated, the stability of bank deposits in a crisis is limited. As for government bonds, massive sales by Libra would likely result in price losses. These problems could be avoided if suppliers of stable coins could use CBDCs as collateral. Adrian and Manicini-Griffoli speak of synthetic CBDCs (sCBDCS).This model is already being practised in China, where Alipay is obliged to keep its accounts with the central bank.

In principle, this could result in ‘narrow banks’, which on their asset side only maintained balances with the central bank and concentrated on the function of payment-service provider. These would be opposed by ‘investment banks’, operating the traditional credit business and offering longer-term, interest-bearing deposits. Compared with all-purpose CBDCs, this arrangement has the advantage that the payments system is operated by private suppliers and not by the central bank. But there is also the risk that the banking system loses the ability to generate loans and a full-money financial system develops.

The introduction of CBDCs, in whatever form, should be subject to very careful consideration. There is little to suggest today that central banks should play an active role as payment-service providers, as would be the case with the introduction of token CBCDs and all-purpose central-bank deposits. Not least, there would be the danger that this would be used by states to achieve even closer monitoring of their citizens.

An interesting innovation, however, would be if CBDCs could only be used as a store of value. Such an asset could only be created by the central bank and it would be particularly interesting for companies and investors who would be confronted with a bail-in in the event of a bank insolvency. Such CBDCs could serve as collateral for payment-service providers issuing a stable coin. But since this could lead to considerable changes in the way the entire financial system functions, no hasty steps should be taken here either.

This article is a joint publication by Social Europe and IPS-Journal

Peter Bofinger
Peter Bofinger

Peter Bofinger is professor of economics at Würzburg University and a former member of the German Council of Economic Experts.

You are here: Home / Economy / Central-bank digital currencies: proceed with caution

Most Popular Posts

Russia,information war Russia is winning the information warAiste Merfeldaite
Nanterre,police Nanterre and the suburbs: the lid comes offJoseph Downing
Russia,nuclear Russia’s dangerous nuclear consensusAna Palacio
Belarus,Lithuania A tale of two countries: Belarus and LithuaniaThorvaldur Gylfason and Eduard Hochreiter
retirement,Finland,ageing,pension,reform Late retirement: possible for many, not for allKati Kuitto

Most Recent Posts

European Union,enlargement,Balkans EU enlargement—back to the futureEmilija Tudzarovska
European Health Data Space,EHDS,Big Tech Fostering public research or boosting Big Tech?Philip Freeman and Jan Willem Goudriaan
migrant workers,non-EU Non-EU migrant workers—the ties that bindLilana Keith
ECB,European Central Bank,deposit facility How the ECB’s ‘deposit facility’ subsidises banksDavid Hollanders
migrant,Europe,workers All work and low pay—Europe’s migrant workforceAnkita Anand

Other Social Europe Publications

strategic autonomy Strategic autonomy
Bildschirmfoto 2023 05 08 um 21.36.25 scaled 1 RE No. 13: Failed Market Approaches to Long-Term Care
front cover Towards a social-democratic century?
Cover e1655225066994 National recovery and resilience plans
Untitled design The transatlantic relationship

Eurofound advertisement

Eurofound Talks: housing

In this episode of the Eurofound Talks podcast, Mary McCaughey speaks with Eurofound’s senior research manager, Hans Dubois, about the issues that feed into housing insecurity in Europe and the actions that need to be taken to address them. Together, they analyse findings from Eurofound’s recent Unaffordable and inadequate housing in Europe report, which presents data from Eurofound’s Living, working and COVID-19 e-survey, European Union Statistics on Income and Living Conditions and input from the Network of Eurofound Correspondents on various indicators of housing security and living conditions.


LISTEN HERE

Foundation for European Progressive Studies Advertisement

The summer issue of the Progressive Post magazine by FEPS is out!

The Special Coverage of this new edition is dedicated to the importance of biodiversity, not only as a good in itself but also for the very existence of humankind. We need a paradigm change in the mostly utilitarian relation humans have with nature.

In this issue, we also look at the hazards of unregulated artificial intelligence, explore the shortcomings of the EU's approach to migration and asylum management, and analyse the social downside of the EU's current ethnically-focused Roma policy.


DOWNLOAD HERE

Hans Böckler Stiftung Advertisement

WSI European Collective Bargaining Report 2022 / 2023

With real wages falling by 4 per cent in 2022, workers in the European Union suffered an unprecedented loss in purchasing power. The reason for this was the rapid increase in consumer prices, behind which nominal wage growth fell significantly. Meanwhile, inflation is no longer driven by energy import prices, but by domestic factors. The increased profit margins of companies are a major reason for persistent inflation. In this difficult environment, trade unions are faced with the challenge of securing real wages—and companies have the responsibility of making their contribution to returning to the path of political stability by reducing excess profits.


DOWNLOAD HERE

ETUI advertisement

The four transitions and the missing one

Europe is at a crossroads, painfully navigating four transitions (green, digital, economic and geopolitical) at once but missing the transformative and ambitious social transition it needs. In other words, if the EU is to withstand the storm, we do not have the luxury of abstaining from reflecting on its social foundations, of which intermittent democratic discontent is only one expression. It is against this background that the ETUI/ETUC publishes its annual flagship publication Benchmarking Working Europe 2023, with the support of more than 70 graphs and a special contribution from two guest editors, Professors Kalypso Nikolaidïs and Albena Azmanova.


DOWNLOAD HERE

About Social Europe

Our Mission

Article Submission

Membership

Advertisements

Legal Disclosure

Privacy Policy

Copyright

Social Europe ISSN 2628-7641

Social Europe Archives

Search Social Europe

Themes Archive

Politics Archive

Economy Archive

Society Archive

Ecology Archive

Follow us

RSS Feed

Follow us on Facebook

Follow us on Twitter

Follow us on LinkedIn

Follow us on YouTube