Social Europe

politics, economy and employment & labour

  • Themes
    • Strategic autonomy
    • War in Ukraine
    • European digital sphere
    • Recovery and resilience
  • Publications
    • Books
    • Dossiers
    • Occasional Papers
    • Research Essays
    • Brexit Paper Series
  • Podcast
  • Videos
  • Newsletter

Almost-new fiscal rules for an old Europe

Enrico D'Elia 11th November 2022

The proposed new fiscal rules may represent modest steps from the status quo. But they are in the right direction.

fiscal rules,Stability and Growth Pact,Maastricht,European Commission,commission,proposal,communication,expenditure,deficit,debt
A rendez-vous in which Europe is set to ease the excessive Maastricht-treaty focus on fiscal discipline (defotoberg/shutterstock.com)

The European Commission has adopted a communication to the European Parliament for upgrading the fiscal rules associated with economic and monetary union, suspended since 2020 amid large economic shocks. The commission’s intention is to design a framework that is ‘simpler, more transparent and effective, with greater national ownership and better enforcement, while allowing for strategic investment and reducing high public debt ratios in a realistic, gradual and sustained manner’.

The proposal is the outcome of long negotiations and public consultation, beginning well before the pandemic and the energy crisis and involving economists, governments and other institutions. Jan Priewe surveyed the main proposals that were on the table this week in Social Europe. The next step is discussion of the commission’s proposal by member-state governments and the European Parliament.

The main aim of the new rulebook is to force member states to reduce public debt along a path that is more feasible (and credible) than that set in the Stability and Growth Pact. This prescribed a reduction of the ratio of debt to gross domestic product by 1/20th of the amount exceeding 60 per cent of GDP every year, keeping the ‘structural’ budget deficit close to an esoteric threshold called the medium-term objective (MTO).

Involved and ineffective

The commission admits that the current pact was strongly focused on fiscal discipline instead of growth, as even the position papers of three orthodox European governments (Spain and the Netherlands jointly and Germany) articulated. It also concedes that the sanctioning procedure was so involved and ineffective that while almost every member state failed to respect the rules at least once during the last decade none was really punished. Just a glance at the multi-layer ‘pyramid’ of steps required to effect the excessive-deficit procedure (in the 2019 edition of the commission’s ready reckoner on the pact) indicates why this happened. Moreover, the MTO has been notorious for volatile and incorrect guidance to national governments, helping amplify rather than smooth the business cycle.


Our job is keeping you informed!


Subscribe to our free newsletter and stay up to date with the latest Social Europe content. We will never send you spam and you can unsubscribe anytime.

Sign up here

Thus, the commission decided to focus on a more transparent measure for evaluating deviation from a prudent fiscal policy, the ‘expenditure benchmark’. This is total public expenditure net of discretionary revenues, excluding interest payments and cyclical spending related to unemployment. The benchmark does not however exclude expenditure on investment, as many stakeholders and scholars had proposed it should.

Formally, the 1/20th debt reduction rule, the ‘structural’ budget deficit based on the controversial ‘output gap’ measure and the MTO thus disappear from the new European fiscal framework. The 3 per cent ceiling for the budget deficit is maintained (since it is prescribed by the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union) but this would be evaluated over a four-year span, instead of being a yearly target exposed to short-term perturbations.

Stable and sustainable

National debt-reduction plans prescribed by the new rules would then have (deliberately) the same average duration as a government, four years, and be revised only in exceptional cases. Thus, each government would pass on a sound fiscal position to the next one. The commission proposes a unified approach (likely very similar to the current methodology) to these multiannual programmes, although they would be subject to modification by the member states through bilateral negotiation. There would be yearly targets for net public expenditure, instead of the budget deficit, consistent with foreseen revenues, debt reduction and GDP.

In the commission’s view, the plans must still ensure that the debt/GDP ratio is put on a stable and sustainable declining path at unchanged policies, and that the budget deficit is below 3 per cent of GDP for the next ten years, albeit with some easing for moderately indebted countries. Member states are classified as high-debt (and high-risk) according to a methodology inspired by the International Monetary Fund, whose main benchmark is a debt/GDP ratio above 90 per cent.

The plan can be extended over a seven-year horizon if the member state is committed to implementing a programme of reform and investment recommended by the commission. Each member state must present an annual report on the plan’s realisation. In evaluating progress, the commission would take into (serious) account other issues included in the Macroeconomic Imbalance Procedure, such as unemployment and territorial disparities. Independent national and European fiscal boards would have a stronger role in assessing deviations from the plan.

The sanctions system would also change. The excessive-deficit procedure would be maintained for breaches of the 3 per cent rule (and opened and closed mechanically for high-risk countries). Nevertheless, fines would be reduced, while a suspension of European funds (including the Recovery and Resilience Facility) and some reputational sanctions would be introduced—such as calling a minister from the state before the European Parliament.

Misleading assessment

A jaundiced observer might say of the new rules what a character in the novel Il Gattopardo (The Leopard) said about Italian unification: ‘If we want things to stay as they are, things will have to change.’ The ‘expenditure benchmark’ seems a rewording of the ‘structural’ deficit criterion, and ‘potential output’ replaces the controversial ‘output gap’ for adjusting fiscal policy to the business cycle in the ten-year projection of debt. The commission will likely take into account some variant of the MTO when it proposes and assesses stabilisation plans. Highly indebted countries may hardly depart from the plans designed by the commission, to avoid negative reactions on the financial markets, which is not so different from the effects of the ‘reinforced surveillance’ foreseen by the current pact.

Discriminating among member states according to their risk level would be a reasonable approach if debt accounting were perfectly comparable across member states. Yet debt measured according to the Maastricht-treaty standard may offer a misleading assessment of the risk each country presents.


We need your support


Social Europe is an independent publisher and we believe in freely available content. For this model to be sustainable, however, we depend on the solidarity of our readers. Become a Social Europe member for less than 5 Euro per month and help us produce more articles, podcasts and videos. Thank you very much for your support!

Become a Social Europe Member

Consider the liabilities of public corporations classified outside general government expenditure (in particular, state-owned investment banks). According to Eurostat, in 2020 these liabilities varied as a ratio of GDP, with the conventional Maastricht debt/GDP ratio in brackets, thus: Greece 171 per cent (206 per cent), Germany 101 (68), the Netherlands 89 (55) and Italy 65 (155). Where the former ratio was higher than the European average, the published debt ratio would represent a comparative underestimate and vice versa.

The average official debt in the European Union was about 90 per cent of GDP in 2020, at the floor of high-risk designation under the new scheme. But that would rise to 156 per cent with the inclusion of these other liabilities—making Germany a high-risk country, while Spain would not be, even though its official debt is 120 per cent of GDP.

Furthermore, there are at least two missing points in the commission’s proposal. The first is the co-ordination of national policies, required by the substantial spillover of fiscal policies across European economies. Thus, the new rules could still be procyclical and risk spreading recessions across the EU, because low-debt countries are still not encouraged to pursue expansive fiscal policies.

Secondly, the ‘expenditure benchmark’ implicitly continues to assume that the fiscal multiplier—the impact on national income of government spending—is zero: otherwise it would be meaningless to monitor expenditure without taking account the effect on revenues and GDP. Yet austerity is acknowledged as counterproductive when the debt/GDP ratio multiplied by the fiscal multiplier exceeds one.

Important achievement

A fair view is however that trying to reform the pact after 25 years is an important achievement in itself. Further good news is the admission that fiscal consolidation is not feasible without economic growth, and that imbalances other than the budget deficit should be taken into serious consideration.

Pursuing multi-annual targets could encourage forward-looking, structural policies instead of short-term items of legislation (sometimes flawed by window-dressing of the public accounts). Increasing the reputational costs and streamlining the penalties for deviations from plans is a strong incentive for governments to be accountable to citizens.

The motivation for enhancing public investment and implementing structural reforms is still weak—holding out only a postponement of fiscal consolidation—but it is a way to focus on the quality of public expenditure and encourage more productive use of tax revenues. Linking the European facilities to the results achieved, as in the NextGenerationEU programme, is good practice. Finally, the new proposal (almost) wipes out from European jargon the 1/20th rule, the ‘output gap’ and the MTO.

Of course, on many issues improved is needed. But we are on the right way.

Enrico DElia 1
Enrico D'Elia

Enrico D’Elia is an economist who has worked, among others, for Eurostat as well as the Ministry of Finance, the Statistical Office and the Institute for Economic Analysis of Italy. He has written about a hundred papers on macroeconomics, behaviour of firms and households, inflation and economic forecasting. The views expressed here are entirely his own.

You are here: Home / Economy / Almost-new fiscal rules for an old Europe

Most Popular Posts

Russian soldiers' mothers,war,Ukraine The Ukraine war and Russian soldiers’ mothersJennifer Mathers and Natasha Danilova
IGU,documents,International Gas Union,lobby,lobbying,sustainable finance taxonomy,green gas,EU,COP ‘Gaslighting’ Europe on fossil fuelsFaye Holder
Schengen,Fortress Europe,Romania,Bulgaria Romania and Bulgaria stuck in EU’s second tierMagdalena Ulceluse
income inequality,inequality,Gini,1 per cent,elephant chart,elephant Global income inequality: time to revise the elephantBranko Milanovic
Orbán,Hungary,Russia,Putin,sanctions,European Union,EU,European Parliament,commission,funds,funding Time to confront Europe’s rogue state—HungaryStephen Pogány

Most Recent Posts

reality check,EU foreign policy,Russia Russia’s invasion of Ukraine—a reality check for the EUHeidi Mauer, Richard Whitman and Nicholas Wright
permanent EU investment fund,Recovery and Resilience Facility,public investment,RRF Towards a permanent EU investment fundPhilipp Heimberger and Andreas Lichtenberger
sustainability,SDGs,Finland Embedding sustainability in a government programmeJohanna Juselius
social dialogue,social partners Social dialogue must be at the heart of Europe’s futureClaes-Mikael Ståhl
Jacinda Ardern,women,leadership,New Zealand What it means when Jacinda Ardern calls timePeter Davis

Other Social Europe Publications

front cover scaled Towards a social-democratic century?
Cover e1655225066994 National recovery and resilience plans
Untitled design The transatlantic relationship
Women Corona e1631700896969 500 Women and the coronavirus crisis
sere12 1 RE No. 12: Why No Economic Democracy in Sweden?

Eurofound advertisement

Eurofound webinar: Making telework work for everyone

Since 2020 more European workers and managers have enjoyed greater flexibility and autonomy in work and are reporting their preference for hybrid working. Also driven by technological developments and structural changes in employment, organisations are now integrating telework more permanently into their workplace.

To reflect on these shifts, on 6 December Eurofound researchers Oscar Vargas and John Hurley explored the challenges and opportunities of the surge in telework, as well as the overall growth of telework and teleworkable jobs in the EU and what this means for workers, managers, companies and policymakers.


WATCH THE WEBINAR HERE

Foundation for European Progressive Studies Advertisement

The winter issue of the Progressive Post magazine from FEPS is out!

The sequence of recent catastrophes has thrust new words into our vocabulary—'polycrisis', for example, even 'permacrisis'. These challenges have multiple origins, reinforce each other and cannot be tackled individually. But could they also be opportunities for the EU?

This issue offers compelling analyses on the European health union, multilateralism and international co-operation, the state of the union, political alternatives to the narrative imposed by the right and much more!


DOWNLOAD HERE

Hans Böckler Stiftung Advertisement

The macroeconomic effects of re-applying the EU fiscal rules

Against the background of the European Commission's reform plans for the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP), this policy brief uses the macroeconometric multi-country model NiGEM to simulate the macroeconomic implications of the most relevant reform options from 2024 onwards. Next to a return to the existing and unreformed rules, the most prominent options include an expenditure rule linked to a debt anchor.

Our results for the euro area and its four biggest economies—France, Italy, Germany and Spain—indicate that returning to the rules of the SGP would lead to severe cuts in public spending, particularly if the SGP rules were interpreted as in the past. A more flexible interpretation would only somewhat ease the fiscal-adjustment burden. An expenditure rule along the lines of the European Fiscal Board would, however, not necessarily alleviate that burden in and of itself.

Our simulations show great care must be taken to specify the expenditure rule, such that fiscal consolidation is achieved in a growth-friendly way. Raising the debt ceiling to 90 per cent of gross domestic product and applying less demanding fiscal adjustments, as proposed by the IMK, would go a long way.


DOWNLOAD HERE

ILO advertisement

Global Wage Report 2022-23: The impact of inflation and COVID-19 on wages and purchasing power

The International Labour Organization's Global Wage Report is a key reference on wages and wage inequality for the academic community and policy-makers around the world.

This eighth edition of the report, The Impact of inflation and COVID-19 on wages and purchasing power, examines the evolution of real wages, giving a unique picture of wage trends globally and by region. The report includes evidence on how wages have evolved through the COVID-19 crisis as well as how the current inflationary context is biting into real wage growth in most regions of the world. The report shows that for the first time in the 21st century real wage growth has fallen to negative values while, at the same time, the gap between real productivity growth and real wage growth continues to widen.

The report analysis the evolution of the real total wage bill from 2019 to 2022 to show how its different components—employment, nominal wages and inflation—have changed during the COVID-19 crisis and, more recently, during the cost-of-living crisis. The decomposition of the total wage bill, and its evolution, is shown for all wage employees and distinguishes between women and men. The report also looks at changes in wage inequality and the gender pay gap to reveal how COVID-19 may have contributed to increasing income inequality in different regions of the world. Together, the empirical evidence in the report becomes the backbone of a policy discussion that could play a key role in a human-centred recovery from the different ongoing crises.


DOWNLOAD HERE

ETUI advertisement

The EU recovery strategy: a blueprint for a more Social Europe or a house of cards?

This new ETUI paper explores the European Union recovery strategy, with a focus on its potentially transformative aspects vis-à-vis European integration and its implications for the social dimension of the EU’s socio-economic governance. In particular, it reflects on whether the agreed measures provide sufficient safeguards against the spectre of austerity and whether these constitute steps away from treating social and labour policies as mere ‘variables’ of economic growth.


DOWNLOAD HERE

About Social Europe

Our Mission

Article Submission

Membership

Advertisements

Legal Disclosure

Privacy Policy

Copyright

Social Europe ISSN 2628-7641

Social Europe Archives

Search Social Europe

Themes Archive

Politics Archive

Economy Archive

Society Archive

Ecology Archive

Follow us

RSS Feed

Follow us on Facebook

Follow us on Twitter

Follow us on LinkedIn

Follow us on YouTube