Social Europe

  • EU Forward Project
  • YouTube
  • Podcast
  • Books
  • Newsletter
  • Membership

The eurozone won’t work without safe government bonds

Fabian Lindner 30th March 2021

The arcane notion of ‘monetary dominance’ lay behind the last eurozone crisis. Unless challenged, it could underlie another one.

government bonds, eurozone crisis, ECB
Fabian Lindner

How safe are eurozone government bonds? This superficially technical question is central to the future of economic and monetary union: without safe bonds, another eurozone crisis could loom right after the pandemic.

The last one erupted in 2010 because of uncertainty about the status of government bonds. Financial-market actors saw those bonds as at risk of default and demanded massively higher interest rates from many governments. These latter, unable to finance deficits, had to implement harsh austerity policies, which led to mass unemployment and nearly brought down the entire euro project.

Only when the then president of the European Central Bank, Mario Draghi, announced in July 2012 that the ECB would do everything it must to save the euro—in an emergency, buying government bonds—did the risk of a sovereign default, and thus interest-rate hikes, dissipate. This was the beginning of the end of the eurozone crisis. Many governments were able to end the disastrous austerity and the economy could finally recover.

While there were similar economic crises in the United States, the United Kingdom and Japan, there was never any doubt in those countries that the central bank would ensure the safety of government bonds. Hence they were spared a sovereign-debt crisis like that in the euro area.

Stabilising employment

Only when government bonds are sufficiently default-proof that investors don’t fear losses will they lend money to governments at low interest rates. Only then will governments be able to increase spending or cut taxes to support corporate and household incomes and thus employment.

The ECB is buying bonds even now in the coronavirus crisis, thus enabling governments to pursue a fiscal policy that stabilises employment. In May last year, however the German Constitutional Court ruled that the ECB was acting outside the European treaties with its bond purchases and that the Bundesbank should no longer participate unless the ECB could dispel doubts that it was acting ultra vires.

Not least in light of such resistance, in March the ECB president, Christine Lagarde, had said that the central bank was not responsible for reducing interest-rate differentials, or spreads, among euro-area government bonds. In doing so, she appeared to be disposing of Draghi’s legacy. Immediately after, interest rates on Italian bonds rose—as the country faced the peak of the pandemic. To be sure, Lagarde rowed back, but spreads remained high into May 2020.

The constitution of the European Stability Mechanism (ESM) also shows how uncertain the status of government bonds remains. The ESM is designed to provide emergency loans to eurozone countries on the verge of default but states only receive the loans under certain conditions. Since if they don’t meet these conditions they will default on their debts, their bonds are still a default risk. This uncertainty is particularly problematic because financial actors can force sovereigns into default if the central bank does not ultimately guarantee the safety of government bonds.

Self-fulfilling expectations

States—as with banks and most corporations—generally do not repay their debts. To roll over maturing debt, they take on new debt. Normally, this works smoothly. But if holders of government bonds fear that a state will stop making payments in the future, they will demand higher interest rates or not roll over the debt at all. In this case, governments are threatened with default and bondholders with losses.

Expectations of a sovereign default can become self-fulfilling prophecies. If an investor believes other investors will not renew their loans for fear of default, she will be in danger of not getting her money back. This investor will consequently not roll over her loans, which will then lead to others not getting their money back. And so on.

This is how bank runs happen. For banks, though, there are two lines of defence. First, central banks usually act as lenders of last resort: against collateral, banks can borrow money from the central bank and thus satisfy a surge of demand from account holders for cash they don’t normally hold. Secondly, there is a government-regulated deposit-guarantee scheme in the euro area, under which bank deposits are guaranteed up to €100,000. These two mechanisms make deposits with banks safe investments: account holders do not have to fear losing their funds, so there is no self-fulfilling expectation of default.

But as long as there is uncertainty about whether government bonds can default, euro-area banks’ debts—their deposits—are safer than government bonds. This is precisely where Draghi and the ECB stepped in: when Draghi announced the purchase of government bonds, interest rates fell. The downward spiral of negative expectations was broken.

Those who are afraid of a government default know they can get their money from the central bank in an emergency. So they do not have to fear losses and continue to lend willingly to states at favorable conditions. At the moment, this is helping governments stabilise the economy and, above all, employment.

‘Monetary dominance’

But if safe government bonds are so important to an economy, why have they been so unsafe in the euro area? This is largely because of the theory of ‘monetary dominance’ upon which it was founded. According to this theory, government bonds must be explicitly at risk of default, as the ‘no-bail-out’ clause of the European treaties was supposed to ensure. Euro-area governments have in effect forbidden each other to guarantee their respective debts, while the central bank is not permitted to lend directly to governments.

With monetary dominance, the highest economic-policy goal—to which others, such as full employment, are subordinated—is low inflation. For a central bank to pursue this goal consistently, the argument goes, it must be absolutely independent of politics: governments would otherwise always have an incentive to incur too much debt and then have the central bank inflate it away.

Only when government bonds are at risk of default can market discipline be ensured, it is claimed: if governments take on too much debt, lenders charge higher interest rates because of the higher risk and government’s appetite for debt decreases—lowering the risk of politically-motivated inflation in the future. This is exactly what happened in the eurozone crisis, but with devastating economic, social and political consequences.

How dangerous would it now be to ease the regime of ‘monetary dominance’ in the euro area? Would there be a threat of hyperinflation, as in Germany after the first world war?

No, as experience illustrates: at least since Draghi’s speech and the subsequent purchases of government bonds, such a strict regime of monetary dominance does not exist in reality in the euro area. But inflation has hardly risen—on the contrary, the central bank is struggling to reach its inflation target of around 2 per cent. Central banks generally are desperately trying to avoid deflation.

In the US, the UK and Japan, however, there has never been strict ‘monetary dominance’ and there has never been any question about whether government bonds are unsafe. This is because the respective central banks have always been willing to buy such bonds. Also in those countries, inflation was not an issue and is not likely to become one.

Unlikely scenario

But could the high mountains of debt which states are now accumulating in the crisis force central banks to bring about inflation in the future? The ECB’s strong independence and its focus on price stability are set against that. If inflation were to rise noticeably—a rather unlikely scenario for the medium term—it could sell government bonds again and raise interest rates. In addition, there are the European fiscal rules which prevent government debt from getting out of hand (albeit they are definitely in need of reform).

In this respect, the pragmatic monetary policy being conducted by the ECB is justified. It protects sovereigns from the ravages of sovereign default risk but its independence means that it can equally counteract excessive inflation.

Yet monetary dominance remains an integral part of the European treaties. To be sure, the ECB does not directly violate it with its bond purchases, because it does not lend to sovereigns directly. It buys government bonds already outstanding in the financial markets, which it is allowed to do. But many think that the bond purchases nevertheless go against the spirit of the treaties. That is one of the reasons why the German Constitutional Court reached its decision. The court has to interpret European law, whether it makes sense or not.

Therefore, there is a real risk that a ruling by a national court which would restrict the purchase of government bonds could lead to them once again being seen as at risk of default, with the corresponding negative consequences. That is why, in the medium term, a commitment is needed from European policy-makers that European government bonds are safe. The euro area cannot afford another explosion of interest rates—with the associated austerity and economic crises.

A German version of this article was published by the Friedrich Ebert Stiftung

Fabian Lindner

Fabian Lindner is a professor of international economics at HTW—University of Applied Science, Berlin.

Harvard University Press Advertisement

Social Europe Ad - Promoting European social policies

We need your help.

Support Social Europe for less than €5 per month and help keep our content freely accessible to everyone. Your support empowers independent publishing and drives the conversations that matter. Thank you very much!

Social Europe Membership

Click here to become a member

Most Recent Articles

u421983467e58be8 81f2 4326 80f2 d452cfe9031e 1 “The Universities Are the Enemy”: Why Europe Must Act NowBartosz Rydliński
u42198345f5300d0e 2 Britain’s COVID Generation: Why Social Democracy Must Seize the MomentJatinder Hayre
u42198346761805ea24 2 Trump’s ‘Golden Era’ Fades as European Allies Face Harsh New RealityFerenc Németh and Peter Kreko
u4219834664e04a 8a1e 4ee0 a6f9 bbc30a79d0b1 2 Closing the Chasm: Central and Eastern Europe’s Continued Minimum Wage ClimbCarlos Vacas-Soriano and Christine Aumayr-Pintar
u421983467f bb39 37d5862ca0d5 0 Ending Britain’s “Brief Encounter” with BrexitStefan Stern

Most Popular Articles

startupsgovernment e1744799195663 Governments Are Not StartupsMariana Mazzucato
u421986cbef 2549 4e0c b6c4 b5bb01362b52 0 American SuicideJoschka Fischer
u42198346769d6584 1580 41fe 8c7d 3b9398aa5ec5 1 Why Trump Keeps Winning: The Truth No One AdmitsBo Rothstein
u421983467 a350a084 b098 4970 9834 739dc11b73a5 1 America Is About to Become the Next BrexitJ Bradford DeLong
u4219834676ba1b3a2 b4e1 4c79 960b 6770c60533fa 1 The End of the ‘West’ and Europe’s FutureGuillaume Duval
u421983462e c2ec 4dd2 90a4 b9cfb6856465 1 The Transatlantic Alliance Is Dying—What Comes Next for Europe?Frank Hoffer
u421983467 2a24 4c75 9482 03c99ea44770 3 Trump’s Trade War Tears North America Apart – Could Canada and Mexico Turn to Europe?Malcolm Fairbrother
u4219834676e2a479 85e9 435a bf3f 59c90bfe6225 3 Why Good Business Leaders Tune Out the Trump Noise and Stay FocusedStefan Stern
u42198346 4ba7 b898 27a9d72779f7 1 Confronting the Pandemic’s Toxic Political LegacyJan-Werner Müller
u4219834676574c9 df78 4d38 939b 929d7aea0c20 2 The End of Progess? The Dire Consequences of Trump’s ReturnJoseph Stiglitz

Eurofound advertisement

Ageing workforce
How are minimum wage levels changing in Europe?

In a new Eurofound Talks podcast episode, host Mary McCaughey speaks with Eurofound expert Carlos Vacas Soriano about recent changes to minimum wages in Europe and their implications.

Listeners can delve into the intricacies of Europe's minimum wage dynamics and the driving factors behind these shifts. The conversation also highlights the broader effects of minimum wage changes on income inequality and gender equality.

Listen to the episode for free. Also make sure to subscribe to Eurofound Talks so you don’t miss an episode!

LISTEN NOW

Foundation for European Progressive Studies Advertisement

Spring Issues

The Spring issue of The Progressive Post is out!


Since President Trump’s inauguration, the US – hitherto the cornerstone of Western security – is destabilising the world order it helped to build. The US security umbrella is apparently closing on Europe, Ukraine finds itself less and less protected, and the traditional defender of free trade is now shutting the door to foreign goods, sending stock markets on a rollercoaster. How will the European Union respond to this dramatic landscape change? .


Among this issue’s highlights, we discuss European defence strategies, assess how the US president's recent announcements will impact international trade and explore the risks  and opportunities that algorithms pose for workers.


READ THE MAGAZINE

Hans Böckler Stiftung Advertisement

WSI Report

WSI Minimum Wage Report 2025

The trend towards significant nominal minimum wage increases is continuing this year. In view of falling inflation rates, this translates into a sizeable increase in purchasing power for minimum wage earners in most European countries. The background to this is the implementation of the European Minimum Wage Directive, which has led to a reorientation of minimum wage policy in many countries and is thus boosting the dynamics of minimum wages. Most EU countries are now following the reference values for adequate minimum wages enshrined in the directive, which are 60% of the median wage or 50 % of the average wage. However, for Germany, a structural increase is still necessary to make progress towards an adequate minimum wage.

DOWNLOAD HERE

S&D Group in the European Parliament advertisement

Cohesion Policy

S&D Position Paper on Cohesion Policy post-2027: a resilient future for European territorial equity”,

Cohesion Policy aims to promote harmonious development and reduce economic, social and territorial disparities between the regions of the Union, and the backwardness of the least favoured regions with a particular focus on rural areas, areas affected by industrial transition and regions suffering from severe and permanent natural or demographic handicaps, such as outermost regions, regions with very low population density, islands, cross-border and mountain regions.

READ THE FULL POSITION PAPER HERE

ETUI advertisement

HESA Magazine Cover

What kind of impact is artificial intelligence (AI) having, or likely to have, on the way we work and the conditions we work under? Discover the latest issue of HesaMag, the ETUI’s health and safety magazine, which considers this question from many angles.

DOWNLOAD HERE

Social Europe

Our Mission

Team

Article Submission

Advertisements

Membership

Social Europe Archives

Themes Archive

Politics Archive

Economy Archive

Society Archive

Ecology Archive

Miscellaneous

RSS Feed

Legal Disclosure

Privacy Policy

Copyright

Social Europe ISSN 2628-7641