Social Europe

politics, economy and employment & labour

  • Themes
    • Strategic autonomy
    • War in Ukraine
    • European digital sphere
    • Recovery and resilience
  • Publications
    • Books
    • Dossiers
    • Occasional Papers
    • Research Essays
    • Brexit Paper Series
  • Podcast
  • Videos
  • Newsletter

The role of public debt in the ‘new normal’

Peter Bofinger 13th February 2023

A Schumpeterian perspective provides new insights for fiscal policy in Europe, Peter Bofinger writes.

debt,Schumpeter
Scaling up: the massive public investments required to meet today’s social challenges cannot be financed out of current government revenues (NavinTar/shutterstock.com)

The crises of recent years have led to impressive paradigm shifts in fiscal policy. With the Recovery and Resilience Facility (RRF), the European Commission has been enabled for the first time to finance broadly based national investment programmes by borrowing on the capital market.

In Germany, the Schuldenbremse (‘debt brake’), inserted in the Grundgesetz (Germany’s 1949 constitution) after the 2008 financial crash, has been challenged by the Zeitenwende (‘changed times’) proclaimed by the chancellor, Olaf Scholz, after the Russian invasion of Ukraine a year ago. With a further amendment to the Grundgesetz, investments for defence can now be financed through debt using a Sondervermögen (‘special fund’) of €100 billion. There is also a debt-financed climate and transformation fund of €60 billion.

In the United States, the president, Joe Biden, has launched the Bipartisan Infrastructure Law, supporting additional infrastructure investment with $550 billion over the next five years; the Inflation Reduction Act, providing almost €400 billion for investments in energy, industry, environment and electromobility, and the CHIPS and Science Act, for which $280 billion is available. With the federal-government deficit forecast to be $1.2 trillion in the fiscal year 2023, one can say that all these measures are ultimately financed by debt.

Theoretical foundations

There has been growing academic interest in the role of public debt, mainly due to the low interest rates which prevailed in recent years. Yet one finds few theoretical foundations for fiscal policy in the ‘new normal’—full employment, where the government is promoting the environmental, energy and digital transitions through debt-financed public investment and industrial policies.


Our job is keeping you informed!


Subscribe to our free newsletter and stay up to date with the latest Social Europe content. We will never send you spam and you can unsubscribe anytime.

Sign up here

The state of thinking can be found in the new book by Olivier Blanchard, former chief economist at the International Monetary Fund, Fiscal Policy Under Low Interest Rates. This presents two theories for public debt, ‘pure public finance’ and ‘functional finance’.

‘Pure public finance’ is based on the neoclassical theory which sees no role for government as investor. Public debt serves as an instrument for transfers to private households, thereby reducing the capital stock and economic growth. Positive effects are only possible with an over-accumulation of capital: when households save too much, the government absorbs a part of private excess saving and redistributes it as transfers for consumption.

‘Functional finance’ corresponds with textbook Keynesianism, which focuses on unemployment. With debt-financed public-expenditure programmes, tax reductions or direct transfers, the government increases aggregate demand until full employment is (re-)established. In essence, modern monetary theory (MMT) can be subsumed under this heading, as its focus is on guaranteeing full employment under decent working conditions.

What is lacking is a theory of public debt which is able to explain the role of debt-financed public investments under full employment. In a recent study, I try to close this gap with a theory of public debt which combines important insights developed by the influential early-20th-century economist Joseph Schumpeter.

Central importance

Schumpeter’s distinction between ‘real analysis’ and ‘monetary analysis’ is of central importance for classifying and understanding the theoretical approaches to public debt. Put simply, in ‘real analysis’ the monetary sphere is identical with the real sphere (which is unfortunately not made explicit in the literature). In ‘monetary analysis’ the real and the monetary sphere are conceptually separate, even if they interact with each other. While ‘real analysis’ shapes neoclassical theory and the ‘loanable funds model’ (incorporating credit), ‘monetary analysis’ characterises the traditional Keynesian investment-savings/liquidity-money (IS/LM) model and MMT (see table).

Classification of theoretical approaches to public debt

 Real analysis (neoclassical theory)Monetary analysis  
UnemploymentNot relevant, as neoclassical theory assumes full employmentPublic debt finances measures to reach full employment Keynesian Theory: IS/LM and MMT; ‘functional finance’ (Blanchard)
Full employmentPublic debt finances transfers to private households Neoclasssical growth theory: ‘pure public finance’ (Blanchard)Public debt finances innovative investments Schumpeterian approach: ‘entrepreneurial state’ (Mazzucato)

A main difference between the two approaches concerns the ‘crowding-out’ effects of public debt. In the real analysis, due to the identity of the real and monetary spheres, public debt causes a real as well as a financial crowding-out of private investment. In the monetary analysis, the ability of the banking system to create credit and money out of nothing prevents a financial crowding-out, but under full employment real crowding out remains a challenge.

This is where Schumpeter’s growth theory comes in. In contrast to neoclassical growth theory, this is not about ever-greater accumulation of a unit good for which there is an invariable ‘production function’, characterising the quantitites of physical inputs and outputs. Schumpeter focuses on how available resources are used differently in innovative production processes: economic development is triggered by ‘revolutionary’ changes, in which ‘spontaneous and discontinuous change in the channels of the flow … forever alters and displaces the equilibrium state previously existing’.

Schumpeter is aware of the crowding-out challenge for the real economy and its inflationary impulses (‘credit inflation’). He sees this as however only a temporary phenomenon, which dissipates when the positive supply effects of innovative investments come into play. In his view, ‘if everything has gone according to expectations’, then ‘the equivalence between the money and commodity streams is more than restored, the credit inflation more than eliminated’.


We need your support


Social Europe is an independent publisher and we believe in freely available content. For this model to be sustainable, however, we depend on the solidarity of our readers. Become a Social Europe member for less than 5 Euro per month and help us produce more articles, podcasts and videos. Thank you very much for your support!

Become a Social Europe Member

His growth theory can be summed up quintessentially as: without a temporary real crowding-out, one cannot have dynamic economic development. In fact, as major central banks (the European Central Bank and the US Federal Reserve) define their inflation targets for the medium term, there should be sufficient space for transitory inflation shocks due to Schumpeterian innovation. In his growth theory, the banker and the private investor are the driving forces of growth: ‘By credit entrepreneurs are given access to the social stream of goods before they have acquired the normal claim to it … It is only thus that the economic development could arise from the mere circular flow in equilibrium.’

‘Entrepreneurial state’

This approach can be modified by replacing the capitalist with the ‘entrepreneurial state’, as described by Mariana Mazzucato. The justification for such a role of the state can be found in the large literature on industrial policy. The uncertainty of fundamental technological innovation, network effects and path dependencies, which make private actors stick to existing technologies, are particularly worth mentioning.

Industrial policy can also be justified by corresponding activities of major economies. China with its ambitious and so far successful industrial policy, largely financed by banks dominated by the state, offers an instructive example of a development strategy based on the concept of monetary analysis in the sense of Schumpeter and Mazzucato.

But the key features of the Schumpeterian approach can also be identified in the design of the RRF. The financing of the programme by the European Union removes the financial constraint for the individual member states. The focus on innovation is meanwhile provided by the requirement that member states dedicate at least 37 per cent of their RRF allocation to measures contributing to climate objectives and at least 20 per cent to digital.

A report by the commission shows that so far both thresholds have been exceeded. A study by Maximilian Freier and colleagues regards this as a blueprint for further initiatives: ‘Thus, the RRF could provide useful lessons for the economic governance framework and for a potential permanent fiscal capacity for the euro area in the future.’

Golden rule

The Schumpeterian design could be also used for the reform of the Stability and Growth Pact. So far the SGP does not allow the debt financing of public investment (a ‘golden rule’). This can be justified by the difficulty to define public investment and the risk that it might cause a ‘deficit bias’ among national governments. But one could think of a project-based golden rule:

  • national governments develop future-oriented projects additional to their existing investment plans,
  • the commission checks whether the projects fulfill these criteria and
  • If the projects are approved, they can debt-financed with the SGP.

In sum, the insights of a Schumpeterian approach provide a theoretical basis for a fiscal policy in the new normal, shaped by the need to transform our economies to deal with the challenges of climate change, disruptions in energy supplies, digitalisation and demographics. These challenges require massive investments—directly by the state or indirectly subsidised—which cannot be financed out of current government revenues.

This is a joint publication by Social Europe and IPS-Journal

Peter Bofinger
Peter Bofinger

Peter Bofinger is professor of economics at Würzburg University and a former member of the German Council of Economic Experts.

You are here: Home / Economy / The role of public debt in the ‘new normal’

Most Popular Posts

meritocracy The myth of meritocracy and the populist threatLisa Pelling
consultants,consultancies,McKinsey Consultants and the crisis of capitalismMariana Mazzucato and Rosie Collington
France,pension reform What’s driving the social crisis in FranceGuillaume Duval
earthquake,Turkey,Erdogan Turkey-Syria earthquake: scandal of being unpreparedDavid Rothery
European civil war,iron curtain,NATO,Ukraine,Gorbachev The new European civil warGuido Montani

Most Recent Posts

gas,IPCC Will this be the last European Gas Conference?Pascoe Sabido
water Confronting the global water crisisMariana Mazzucato, Ngozi Okonjo-Iweala, Johan Rockström and 1 more
Hungary,social media,women Hungary’s ‘propaganda machine’ attacks womenLucy Martirosyan
carbon removal,carbon farming,nature Environmental stewardship yes, ‘carbon farming’ noWijnand Stoefs
IRA,industrial policy,inflation reduction act The IRA and European industrial policyPaul Sweeney

Other Social Europe Publications

front cover scaled Towards a social-democratic century?
Cover e1655225066994 National recovery and resilience plans
Untitled design The transatlantic relationship
Women Corona e1631700896969 500 Women and the coronavirus crisis
sere12 1 RE No. 12: Why No Economic Democracy in Sweden?

ILO advertisement

Global Wage Report 2022-23: The impact of inflation and COVID-19 on wages and purchasing power

The International Labour Organization's Global Wage Report is a key reference on wages and wage inequality for the academic community and policy-makers around the world.

This eighth edition of the report, The Impact of inflation and COVID-19 on wages and purchasing power, examines the evolution of real wages, giving a unique picture of wage trends globally and by region. The report includes evidence on how wages have evolved through the COVID-19 crisis as well as how the current inflationary context is biting into real wage growth in most regions of the world. The report shows that for the first time in the 21st century real wage growth has fallen to negative values while, at the same time, the gap between real productivity growth and real wage growth continues to widen.

The report analysis the evolution of the real total wage bill from 2019 to 2022 to show how its different components—employment, nominal wages and inflation—have changed during the COVID-19 crisis and, more recently, during the cost-of-living crisis. The decomposition of the total wage bill, and its evolution, is shown for all wage employees and distinguishes between women and men. The report also looks at changes in wage inequality and the gender pay gap to reveal how COVID-19 may have contributed to increasing income inequality in different regions of the world. Together, the empirical evidence in the report becomes the backbone of a policy discussion that could play a key role in a human-centred recovery from the different ongoing crises.


DOWNLOAD HERE

ETUI advertisement

The four transitions and the missing one

Europe is at a crossroads, painfully navigating four transitions (green, digital, economic and geopolitical) at once but missing the transformative and ambitious social transition it needs. In other words, if the EU is to withstand the storm, we do not have the luxury of abstaining from reflecting on its social foundations, of which intermittent democratic discontent is only one expression. It is against this background that the ETUI/ETUC publishes its annual flagship publication Benchmarking Working Europe 2023, with the support of more than 70 graphs and a special contribution from two guest editors, Professors Kalypso Nikolaidïs and Albena Azmanova.


DOWNLOAD HERE

Eurofound advertisement

#AskTheExpert webinar—Key ingredients for the future of work: job quality and gender equality

Eurofound’s head of information and communication, Mary McCaughey, its senior research manager, Agnès Parent-Thirion, and research manager, Jorge Cabrita, explore the findings from the recently published European Working Conditions Telephone Survey (EWCTS) in an #AskTheExpert webinar. This survey of more than 70,000 workers in 36 European countries provides a wide-ranging picture of job quality across countries, occupations, sectors and age groups and by gender in the context of the Covid-19 pandemic. It confirms persistent gender segregation in sectors, occupations and workplaces, indicating that we are a long way from the goals of equal opportunities for women and men at work and equal access to key decision-making positions in the workplace.


WATCH HERE

Foundation for European Progressive Studies Advertisement

Let’s end involuntary unemployment!

What is the best way to fight unemployment? We want to know your opinion, to understand better the potential of an EU-wide permanent programme for direct and guaranteed public-service employment.

In collaboration with Our Global Moment, Fondazione Pietro Nenni and other progressive organisations across Europe, we launched an EU-wide survey on the perception of unemployment and publicly funded jobs, exploring ways to bring innovation in public sector-led job creation.


TAKE THE SURVEY HERE

Hans Böckler Stiftung Advertisement

The macroeconomic effects of re-applying the EU fiscal rules

Against the background of the European Commission's reform plans for the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP), this policy brief uses the macroeconometric multi-country model NiGEM to simulate the macroeconomic implications of the most relevant reform options from 2024 onwards. Next to a return to the existing and unreformed rules, the most prominent options include an expenditure rule linked to a debt anchor.

Our results for the euro area and its four biggest economies—France, Italy, Germany and Spain—indicate that returning to the rules of the SGP would lead to severe cuts in public spending, particularly if the SGP rules were interpreted as in the past. A more flexible interpretation would only somewhat ease the fiscal-adjustment burden. An expenditure rule along the lines of the European Fiscal Board would, however, not necessarily alleviate that burden in and of itself.

Our simulations show great care must be taken to specify the expenditure rule, such that fiscal consolidation is achieved in a growth-friendly way. Raising the debt ceiling to 90 per cent of gross domestic product and applying less demanding fiscal adjustments, as proposed by the IMK, would go a long way.


DOWNLOAD HERE

About Social Europe

Our Mission

Article Submission

Membership

Advertisements

Legal Disclosure

Privacy Policy

Copyright

Social Europe ISSN 2628-7641

Social Europe Archives

Search Social Europe

Themes Archive

Politics Archive

Economy Archive

Society Archive

Ecology Archive

Follow us

RSS Feed

Follow us on Facebook

Follow us on Twitter

Follow us on LinkedIn

Follow us on YouTube