Social Europe

  • EU Forward Project
  • YouTube
  • Podcast
  • Books
  • Newsletter
  • Membership

European recovery: we need both joint debt and taxes

Carlo D'Ippoliti 21st March 2019

Carlo D’Ippoliti adds to the Social Europe debate on a European recovery, contending that the proposals by Varoufakis and Piketty each have merits and should be synthesised.

European recovery

Carlo D’Ippoliti

Regardless of its electoral fortunes, the pan-European DiEM25 party of Yanis Varoufakis is driving a debate within the European left, parallel to that within the centre-right ignited by Emmanuel Macron’s En Marche—see, for example, the recent reply by Annegret Kramp-Karrenbauer).

As readers of Social Europe know, Varoufakis opened the debate, noting that, since the 2011-12 peak of the crisis, proposals for reform of the eurozone or the wider European Union had become less aspirational. He singled out a group of economists championed by Thomas Piketty, who had recently produced a plan for the introduction of progressive taxes on corporations and the ‘top 1 per cent’, as well as environmental taxes, to complement institutional reforms aimed at democratising the EU.

Varoufakis contrasted this with his party’s plan for a ‘Green New Deal’, based on the large-scale issuance by the European Investment Bank (EIB) of common bonds, which would be backed by the European Central Bank (ECB). He deemed the Green New Deal preferable because right now Europe needed safe financial assets, real investments and expansionary policies.

Moreover, as the gilets jaunes movement had shown, a major political weakness of the plan of Piketty et al would be that there was currently no political room for new taxes of any kind. Finally, Varoufakis criticised the lack of redistribution among European countries in the plan, asking why we would need more EU democracy if tax-and-spend were to remain nation-based.

Piketty et al answered that their proposal did not encompass redistribution among countries—even though the authors still supported the idea—because this was politically non-viable at the moment. Rather, their plan aimed to reduce inequality within countries, because a rich Greek should contribute to crisis resolution more than a poor German (this only partially answered the question). On the crucial issue of financing, through taxes or debt, they defended the tax approach because their proposed objects of expenditure were, in their view, ‘public goods’ to which the collectivity as a whole should contribute.

Answers by James Galbraith and Stuart Holland followed. These noted that it was widely accepted that projects with a future positive cash flow could be financed with new debt, especially in the current environment of low demand and low interest rates. Moreover, the plan of Piketty et al would require EU treaty changes, whereas the issuance of bonds by the EIB would not.

Europe-wide debate

This is interesting for a number of reasons. First, it could finally be the start of a common Europe-wide political debate, even though there is an obvious risk of it being limited to a small cosmopolitan elite of intellectuals already debating in academic settings (maybe because we are still discussing grand plans, rather than specific measures which could resonate with the public at large).

Secondly, it highlights a major weakness of the stance of European social democrats in the recent past. In many countries they bought into the competitiveness mantra, adhering to the European long-term strategy based on cost (as opposed to non-price) competition—often even promoting austerity. At the same time, most social democrats have tended to resist cuts to social spending, as the last signifier of their differences with the conservatives.

Except for short periods, one cannot credibly cut taxation and social contributions without also reducing welfare expenditures. If they are to regain credibility and they want to defend social expenditure, social democrats must convincingly argue for higher taxes whenever the welfare state is in a ‘structural’ deficit or—which is the same—when they propose new recurrent expenditures. Otherwise, voters will expect a welfare state constantly exhibiting a deficit to be sooner or later downsized. Julio López G recently added that additional taxes may also be unavoidable, if more redistribution is to be sought.

So Piketty et al have a point in proposing new taxes. And it is curious that they decided to highlight the public-goods nature of their proposal, when they could have argued that current expenditure cannot systematically be financed by borrowing. (An important technical qualification here, however, is that deficits are sustainable up to the value given by the difference between the rate of GDP growth and the average interest rate on sovereign bonds—the ‘responsible’ target is not zero.)

Yet, for many years now Europeans have discussed the ‘golden rule’ that deficits can and should be used to finance investments, and investments are exactly what Varoufakis’ plan foresees (and, partly, that of Piketty et al too). Since most European countries’ economies currently operate below potential, and within the EU divergence is amplifying, debt-financed investments do seem part of the solution—it is difficult not to see the solid merit of Varoufakis’ argument.

Implementation difficulties

Rather, the difficulties with the Green New Deal plan are of implementation. One is what counts as ‘investment’ and can therefore be legitimately debt-financed. For example, at the peak of the crisis the Italian government proposed a golden rule which included ‘social investments’ or at least investment in ‘human capital’. This would obviously be resisted by fiscally conservative administrations, interpreting it as opening the way to systematic debt financing of the welfare state. Moreover, the EIB itself might oppose large-scale expansions of its scope which, until the intervention of the ECB was more clearly defined, could put its ‘precious’ triple-A rating at risk.

A deepening of the EU’s democracy would be a large part of the solution to these issues. Anyway, implementation difficulties cannot be decisive when the future of the EU so clearly depends on deep and radical reforms, and on essential investments in the depressed areas.

What we need is an integration of the two plans. Let us not forget that public capital (past investments) requires maintenance and that many other current expenditures are equally valuable (education, health, long-term care and so on)—these cannot be systematically debt-financed. As the late Padoa Schioppa explained, the left should more explicitly reassert that taxes are a beautiful thing: they are how a civilised citizenry meets its collective needs. As much as it was wrong back then for social democrats to jump on the austerity bandwagon, it would be wrong now to think that we could live off investments alone.

Carlo D'Ippoliti

Carlo D'Ippoliti is associate professor of economics at Sapienza University of Rome, where he co-ordinates the Minerva Laboratory on Gender Equality and Diversity. He is editor of the open access economics journal PSL Quarterly Review.

Harvard University Press Advertisement

Social Europe Ad - Promoting European social policies

We need your help.

Support Social Europe for less than €5 per month and help keep our content freely accessible to everyone. Your support empowers independent publishing and drives the conversations that matter. Thank you very much!

Social Europe Membership

Click here to become a member

Most Recent Articles

u4219834647f 0894ae7ca865 3 Europe’s Businesses Face a Quiet Takeover as US Investors CapitaliseTej Gonza and Timothée Duverger
u4219834674930082ba55 0 Portugal’s Political Earthquake: Centrist Grip Crumbles, Right AscendsEmanuel Ferreira
u421983467e58be8 81f2 4326 80f2 d452cfe9031e 1 “The Universities Are the Enemy”: Why Europe Must Act NowBartosz Rydliński
u42198345f5300d0e 2 Britain’s COVID Generation: Why Social Democracy Must Seize the MomentJatinder Hayre
u42198346761805ea24 2 Trump’s ‘Golden Era’ Fades as European Allies Face Harsh New RealityFerenc Németh and Peter Kreko

Most Popular Articles

startupsgovernment e1744799195663 Governments Are Not StartupsMariana Mazzucato
u421986cbef 2549 4e0c b6c4 b5bb01362b52 0 American SuicideJoschka Fischer
u42198346769d6584 1580 41fe 8c7d 3b9398aa5ec5 1 Why Trump Keeps Winning: The Truth No One AdmitsBo Rothstein
u421983467 a350a084 b098 4970 9834 739dc11b73a5 1 America Is About to Become the Next BrexitJ Bradford DeLong
u4219834676ba1b3a2 b4e1 4c79 960b 6770c60533fa 1 The End of the ‘West’ and Europe’s FutureGuillaume Duval
u421983462e c2ec 4dd2 90a4 b9cfb6856465 1 The Transatlantic Alliance Is Dying—What Comes Next for Europe?Frank Hoffer
u421983467 2a24 4c75 9482 03c99ea44770 3 Trump’s Trade War Tears North America Apart – Could Canada and Mexico Turn to Europe?Malcolm Fairbrother
u4219834676e2a479 85e9 435a bf3f 59c90bfe6225 3 Why Good Business Leaders Tune Out the Trump Noise and Stay FocusedStefan Stern
u42198346 4ba7 b898 27a9d72779f7 1 Confronting the Pandemic’s Toxic Political LegacyJan-Werner Müller
u4219834676574c9 df78 4d38 939b 929d7aea0c20 2 The End of Progess? The Dire Consequences of Trump’s ReturnJoseph Stiglitz

S&D Group in the European Parliament advertisement

Cohesion Policy

S&D Position Paper on Cohesion Policy post-2027: a resilient future for European territorial equity”,

Cohesion Policy aims to promote harmonious development and reduce economic, social and territorial disparities between the regions of the Union, and the backwardness of the least favoured regions with a particular focus on rural areas, areas affected by industrial transition and regions suffering from severe and permanent natural or demographic handicaps, such as outermost regions, regions with very low population density, islands, cross-border and mountain regions.

READ THE FULL POSITION PAPER HERE

ETUI advertisement

HESA Magazine Cover

What kind of impact is artificial intelligence (AI) having, or likely to have, on the way we work and the conditions we work under? Discover the latest issue of HesaMag, the ETUI’s health and safety magazine, which considers this question from many angles.

DOWNLOAD HERE

Eurofound advertisement

Ageing workforce
How are minimum wage levels changing in Europe?

In a new Eurofound Talks podcast episode, host Mary McCaughey speaks with Eurofound expert Carlos Vacas Soriano about recent changes to minimum wages in Europe and their implications.

Listeners can delve into the intricacies of Europe's minimum wage dynamics and the driving factors behind these shifts. The conversation also highlights the broader effects of minimum wage changes on income inequality and gender equality.

Listen to the episode for free. Also make sure to subscribe to Eurofound Talks so you don’t miss an episode!

LISTEN NOW

Foundation for European Progressive Studies Advertisement

Spring Issues

The Spring issue of The Progressive Post is out!


Since President Trump’s inauguration, the US – hitherto the cornerstone of Western security – is destabilising the world order it helped to build. The US security umbrella is apparently closing on Europe, Ukraine finds itself less and less protected, and the traditional defender of free trade is now shutting the door to foreign goods, sending stock markets on a rollercoaster. How will the European Union respond to this dramatic landscape change? .


Among this issue’s highlights, we discuss European defence strategies, assess how the US president's recent announcements will impact international trade and explore the risks  and opportunities that algorithms pose for workers.


READ THE MAGAZINE

Hans Böckler Stiftung Advertisement

WSI Report

WSI Minimum Wage Report 2025

The trend towards significant nominal minimum wage increases is continuing this year. In view of falling inflation rates, this translates into a sizeable increase in purchasing power for minimum wage earners in most European countries. The background to this is the implementation of the European Minimum Wage Directive, which has led to a reorientation of minimum wage policy in many countries and is thus boosting the dynamics of minimum wages. Most EU countries are now following the reference values for adequate minimum wages enshrined in the directive, which are 60% of the median wage or 50 % of the average wage. However, for Germany, a structural increase is still necessary to make progress towards an adequate minimum wage.

DOWNLOAD HERE

Social Europe

Our Mission

Team

Article Submission

Advertisements

Membership

Social Europe Archives

Themes Archive

Politics Archive

Economy Archive

Society Archive

Ecology Archive

Miscellaneous

RSS Feed

Legal Disclosure

Privacy Policy

Copyright

Social Europe ISSN 2628-7641