Social Europe

  • EU Forward Project
  • YouTube
  • Podcast
  • Books
  • Newsletter
  • Membership

The Ordoliberal Ghost

Marcel Hadeed 2nd August 2017

Marcel Hadeed

Marcel Hadeed

Driven by the politics of resolving the Euro crisis, ordoliberalism has sparked great academic interest in recent years. To many observers, this school of thought explains Germany‘s approach towards overcoming that crisis and ensuring the Eurozone’s future stability. Much has been written about its influence on the new Eurozone macroeconomic governance regime but few attempts have been made to answer the underlying question: what is ordoliberalism?

Its original concepts were developed at the Freiburg School by economist Walter Eucken and lawyer Franz Böhm, who first described its core tenets in the Ordo-Manifesto of 1936. In its origins, ordoliberalism was a comprehensive theory of social order, aiming at guaranteeing the simultaneous realization of personal liberty, a fair distribution of means and power, and the broadest possible satisfaction of societal needs. Like Hayekian neo-liberalism, it is centered on the belief that price mechanism, in an environment of perfect competition, is the best possible means for resource allocation. Such liberalism – and here the ‘ordos’ markedly diverge from Hayek – could only be maintained through public regulation of markets. The invisible hand of the markets must be governed by the visible hand of coercive law informed by economic theory.

But how should such market intervention be guided? The ‘ordos’ rejected the then prevalent approaches, arguing that both laissez-faire and planned economies featured economic concentration in the hands of the few –the capitalist conglomerate or the state – to the detriment of society at large. Either way, competition would be impeded. Instead, Eucken devised a system in which the state’s role was limited to the establishment and governance of a system of undistorted competition: the Competitive Order. Eucken declared economists and lawyers as the only ones knowledgeable and independent enough to conduct sensible economic policy and concluded that Ordnungspolitik must therefore be left to them, away from political pressures. Such macroeconomic governance by law is grounded in infallible “fundamental principles” acquiring constitutional status (hence, ordo). Eucken observed that they could manifest themselves differently given individual national historic contexts, reflecting societal norms that have acquired legitimacy over time. Linking the legal, social and economic orders is an essential feature of ordoliberalism – it is more than just an economic theory.

These considerations are often forgotten in the current debate about ordoliberalism. Besides the German reluctance to engage in expansionary monetary policy (consensually attributed to an ordoliberal precept of price stability), it is the codification of fiscal policy that has inspired the “ordoliberalization of Europe” hypothesis. The strengthened macroeconomic supervision introduced by the six-pack and two-pack legislative measures and the debt brake contained in the fiscal compact (TSCG) seem consistent with the “economics by law” approach associated with ordoliberalism.

Three observations further this belief: first, the aim of the new rules has publicly been the establishment of a level playing field and the strengthening of competition. Secondly, the means of devising fiscal rules shrinks politicians’ room to shape socio-economic outcomes. Lastly, leading German figures such as Bundesbank director Jens Weidmann and finance minister Wolfgang Schäuble often refer to Eucken to give German Krisenpolitik a frame of intellectual authority, and to justify austerity policies that elsewhere in Europe are considered unjust, undemocratic and/or lacking in solidarity.

The director of the Walter Eucken Institute and chairman of the German Council of Economic Experts, Lars Feld disagrees with the accusation that all German actions are ordoliberal. After all, he argues, Germany accepted the establishment of the European Stability Mechanism, compromising on the principle of liability. However, both sides agree that the further codification of the macroeconomic governance regime is compatible with the ordoliberal vision.

How would Walter Eucken view such a development? There are three striking observations:

  1. The strengthened governance regime continues Maastricht’s “one size fits all” approach. Its logic of convergence forces Member States to dismantle their historic institutional arrangements. Using such a single template alone contradicts Eucken’s call for the appreciation of national contexts when implementing the fundamental principles. Eucken had warned of the futility of transnational economic constitutions, believing it impossible to form a single valid framework for different nations. Surprisingly, Eucken emerges here as an advocate of flexibility in the Eurozone’s governance.
  2. The very essence of ordoliberalism is governance by law, not by rules. There are important and delicate differences between these. The former must display the legitimacy, societal reflexivity and specificity that the latter can lack. This calls for the basis of economic policy to be anchored in the constitution and grounded in juridical criteria. These criteria must be implemented and evaluated by courts, not politicians. The legal framework needs legitimacy, and thus – at least in democracies – a popular mandate for its establishment. By way of contrast, the current EU economic regime has never witnessed a popular vote on its establishment, nor is economic policy conducted by the ECJ. Instead, it is the Council that maintains key prerogatives: It evaluates economic policy, breaches of agreements, exemptions, and ultimately it can initiate correctional and punitive measures. Both the excessive deficit procedure and the excessive imbalance procedure require its political consent. Thus, the post-crisis EMU is subject to exactly those political pressures against which Eucken wanted to guard economic policy.
  3. The powers of Commission and Council contradict Eucken in another related issue. To recall, Eucken was skeptical of active macroeconomic steering, believing economic interactions to be too complex to be determined by any other mechanism than the price signal. No matter what the aim of “crisis law” is, the means of “ad hoc” Council decisions fundamentally contradict the systematic and limited nature of ordoliberal Ordnungspolitik.

Paradoxically, Eucken’s contemporary disciples are the strongest advocates for an economic governance framework that violates some of his core tenets. The current discussion of ordoliberalism is flawed and might lead the debate about the Eurozone’s future towards theoretical futility. Those invoking the ordoliberal legacy should be more cautious and precise whereas the critics should learn to distinguish between theoretical concepts and political practices.

Marcel Hadeed

Marcel Hadeed is co-director of Polis180’s EU program. He is a recent graduate with a Master of Public Policy from the Hertie School of Governance and has a background in international relations. Topics of particular interest are European governance structures and socio-economic arrangements.

Harvard University Press Advertisement

Social Europe Ad - Promoting European social policies

We need your help.

Support Social Europe for less than €5 per month and help keep our content freely accessible to everyone. Your support empowers independent publishing and drives the conversations that matter. Thank you very much!

Social Europe Membership

Click here to become a member

Most Recent Articles

u4219834664e04a 8a1e 4ee0 a6f9 bbc30a79d0b1 2 Closing the Chasm: Central and Eastern Europe’s Continued Minimum Wage ClimbCarlos Vacas-Soriano and Christine Aumayr-Pintar
u421983467f bb39 37d5862ca0d5 0 Ending Britain’s “Brief Encounter” with BrexitStefan Stern
u421983485 2 The Future of American Soft PowerJoseph S. Nye
u4219834676d582029 038f 486a 8c2b fe32db91c9b0 2 Trump Can’t Kill the Boom: Why the US Economy Will Roar Despite HimNouriel Roubini
u42198346fb0de2b847 0 How the Billionaire Boom Is Fueling Inequality—and Threatening DemocracyFernanda Balata and Sebastian Mang

Most Popular Articles

startupsgovernment e1744799195663 Governments Are Not StartupsMariana Mazzucato
u421986cbef 2549 4e0c b6c4 b5bb01362b52 0 American SuicideJoschka Fischer
u42198346769d6584 1580 41fe 8c7d 3b9398aa5ec5 1 Why Trump Keeps Winning: The Truth No One AdmitsBo Rothstein
u421983467 a350a084 b098 4970 9834 739dc11b73a5 1 America Is About to Become the Next BrexitJ Bradford DeLong
u4219834676ba1b3a2 b4e1 4c79 960b 6770c60533fa 1 The End of the ‘West’ and Europe’s FutureGuillaume Duval
u421983462e c2ec 4dd2 90a4 b9cfb6856465 1 The Transatlantic Alliance Is Dying—What Comes Next for Europe?Frank Hoffer
u421983467 2a24 4c75 9482 03c99ea44770 3 Trump’s Trade War Tears North America Apart – Could Canada and Mexico Turn to Europe?Malcolm Fairbrother
u4219834676e2a479 85e9 435a bf3f 59c90bfe6225 3 Why Good Business Leaders Tune Out the Trump Noise and Stay FocusedStefan Stern
u42198346 4ba7 b898 27a9d72779f7 1 Confronting the Pandemic’s Toxic Political LegacyJan-Werner Müller
u4219834676574c9 df78 4d38 939b 929d7aea0c20 2 The End of Progess? The Dire Consequences of Trump’s ReturnJoseph Stiglitz

KU Leuven advertisement

The Politics of Unpaid Work

This new book published by Oxford University Press presents the findings of the multiannual ERC research project “Researching Precariousness Across the Paid/Unpaid Work Continuum”,
led by Valeria Pulignano (KU Leuven), which are very important for the prospects of a more equal Europe.

Unpaid labour is no longer limited to the home or volunteer work. It infiltrates paid jobs, eroding rights and deepening inequality. From freelancers’ extra hours to care workers’ unpaid duties, it sustains precarity and fuels inequity. This book exposes the hidden forces behind unpaid labour and calls for systemic change to confront this pressing issue.

DOWNLOAD HERE FOR FREE

ETUI advertisement

HESA Magazine Cover

What kind of impact is artificial intelligence (AI) having, or likely to have, on the way we work and the conditions we work under? Discover the latest issue of HesaMag, the ETUI’s health and safety magazine, which considers this question from many angles.

DOWNLOAD HERE

Eurofound advertisement

Ageing workforce
How are minimum wage levels changing in Europe?

In a new Eurofound Talks podcast episode, host Mary McCaughey speaks with Eurofound expert Carlos Vacas Soriano about recent changes to minimum wages in Europe and their implications.

Listeners can delve into the intricacies of Europe's minimum wage dynamics and the driving factors behind these shifts. The conversation also highlights the broader effects of minimum wage changes on income inequality and gender equality.

Listen to the episode for free. Also make sure to subscribe to Eurofound Talks so you don’t miss an episode!

LISTEN NOW

Foundation for European Progressive Studies Advertisement

Spring Issues

The Spring issue of The Progressive Post is out!


Since President Trump’s inauguration, the US – hitherto the cornerstone of Western security – is destabilising the world order it helped to build. The US security umbrella is apparently closing on Europe, Ukraine finds itself less and less protected, and the traditional defender of free trade is now shutting the door to foreign goods, sending stock markets on a rollercoaster. How will the European Union respond to this dramatic landscape change? .


Among this issue’s highlights, we discuss European defence strategies, assess how the US president's recent announcements will impact international trade and explore the risks  and opportunities that algorithms pose for workers.


READ THE MAGAZINE

Hans Böckler Stiftung Advertisement

WSI Report

WSI Minimum Wage Report 2025

The trend towards significant nominal minimum wage increases is continuing this year. In view of falling inflation rates, this translates into a sizeable increase in purchasing power for minimum wage earners in most European countries. The background to this is the implementation of the European Minimum Wage Directive, which has led to a reorientation of minimum wage policy in many countries and is thus boosting the dynamics of minimum wages. Most EU countries are now following the reference values for adequate minimum wages enshrined in the directive, which are 60% of the median wage or 50 % of the average wage. However, for Germany, a structural increase is still necessary to make progress towards an adequate minimum wage.

DOWNLOAD HERE

Social Europe

Our Mission

Team

Article Submission

Advertisements

Membership

Social Europe Archives

Themes Archive

Politics Archive

Economy Archive

Society Archive

Ecology Archive

Miscellaneous

RSS Feed

Legal Disclosure

Privacy Policy

Copyright

Social Europe ISSN 2628-7641