Social Europe

politics, economy and employment & labour

  • Themes
    • Global cities
    • Strategic autonomy
    • War in Ukraine
    • European digital sphere
    • Recovery and resilience
  • Publications
    • Books
    • Dossiers
    • Occasional Papers
    • Research Essays
    • Brexit Paper Series
  • Podcast
  • Videos
  • Newsletter
  • Membership

Interest-rate rises versus the public interest

Andris Šuvajevs 14th November 2022

In going along with rate rises, European governments are saving the European Central Bank—not their societies.

rate rises,interest rates,European Central Bank,bank,ECB,inflation,prices.fiscal policy,public investment
Under a cloud: the European Central Bank has successively raised interest rates—not because that is what is right, faced with supply-side inflation, but because that is the policy lever it can pull (klptgrph/shutterstock.com)

The current mix of high inflation and recession in Europe has put any green, leftist or social-democratic party in an unenviable position. The European Central Bank is raising rates and there is nothing politicians can do about it. At the same time, these very same rate rises prevent meaningful public investment, as the costs of government borrowing rise too.

The mainstream, centrist view is that one can only hope to provide a temporary, targeted cushion to vulnerable households. Any other spending plans are quickly deemed implausible or irresponsible by fiscal hawks, who point to rising bond yields as seemingly incontrovertible evidence.

Yet enthusiasm for raising rates in a recessionary environment is only one of the many contradictions at the heart of European monetary and fiscal policy. If these are not solved, poverty, inequality and social insecurity are bound to rise.

Incoherence and deadlock

Why is this contradiction allowed to play out? The answer is part conceptual, part institutional.


Become part of our Community of Thought Leaders


Get fresh perspectives delivered straight to your inbox. Sign up for our newsletter to receive thought-provoking opinion articles and expert analysis on the most pressing political, economic and social issues of our time. Join our community of engaged readers and be a part of the conversation.

Sign up here

Conceptually, it is accepted that inflation is driven by supply issues related to the war in Ukraine, as well as pandemic-induced disruption of supply chains. But contemporary public financial institutions—including central banks—are designed to tackle demand-driven problems, such as economic overheating or a wage-price spiral.

These distinctions may not be clear to the general public, which enables central bankers and politicians endorsing rate rises to elide supportive claims about ‘pent-up’ demand going back to the Covid-19 fiscal stimulus, the current threat of a wage-price spiral (for which there is no evidence) and future expectations that inflation will rise. The conceptual incoherence is compounded by the institutional deadlock, described by Daniela Gabor, in which the ECB is trapped.

Appropriate response

The bank fears the dominance of fiscal over monetary policy, as in earlier Keynesian times. It knows that it cannot do anything about the sources of inflation. Yet it is not ready to condone an appropriate institutional response to the crisis, in the (Keynesian) form of public investment, which would require holding rates or pinning down bond yields.

Europe faces the challenge, on the supply side, of having to reorient its entire energy regime, unimaginable without large-scale fiscal-policy commitment. The ECB might hope that the energy transition would be carried out by the private sector. But then another contradiction arises: how can such investment be induced by raising the cost of capital?

The ECB speaks about engaging in swift action in an uncertain environment, as if this justified rate rises. Yet swift action is actually needed by eurozone governments—the only entities able to mobilise resources on a sufficiently large scale—and the bank’s activity effectively prevents it.

Contradiction turns into hypocrisy when central bankers speak about the need for policy alignment among the various actors. For it is difficult to work with someone who insists that they, and they alone, can set the course of action while no one else can tell them—being ‘independent’ of accountability—what to do.

European governments are like hostages given a false sense of agency: they act seemingly guided by their free will, when in reality everything is already determined for them. In a recessionary environment, they should be thinking about the appropriate size of a compensating fiscal stimulus, yet instead they are thinking about how to keep the stimulus as small as possible.

Perverse outcome

The final contradiction concerns the intended versus possible outcomes of raising rates. They are supposed to bring down inflation by making new investment more costly, alongside the increased expense of servicing debts. This drains some demand from the economy and reduces the volume of investment, recalibrating expectations of growth, and price rises, and thus wage demands.


Support Progressive Ideas: Become a Social Europe Member!


Support independent publishing and progressive ideas by becoming a Social Europe member for less than 5 Euro per month. You can help us create more high-quality articles, podcasts and videos that challenge conventional thinking and foster a more informed and democratic society. Join us in our mission - your support makes all the difference!

Become a Social Europe Member

As noted, this mechanism works as intended when inflation is demand-driven. But when prices rise due to supply issues (the elevated cost of energy in this case) demand is already becoming drained. And raising interest rates, instead of depressing inflation, could add to it in at least two ways.

First, interest paid by governments will necessarily increase. Unless governments are then willing to tolerate spending cuts, in an already recessionary environment, this will necessitate additional public spending and so borrowing. This in turn will increase inequality—the higher interest payments flowing to well-off bondholders—without adding to the productive capacity of the economy (as would additional public investment).

Secondly, while raising rates should eliminate any risk of a wage-price spiral, as businesses cut investment and unemployment increases, moderating the bargaining position of labour, it also increases households’ debt-servicing costs. And while lowered union density would militate against effective wage demands, well-paid professionals who tend to have bigger mortgages and debts will likely see a bigger rise in interest payments in absolute terms—and are in a better bargaining position to demand higher salaries.

Thus, raising rates may produce the very outcomes it supposedly seeks to tackle.

Policy mix

For the political left, the alternative policy mix should be clear: in the short-term keep rates low (and co-ordinate this globally to prevent their competitive elevation), provide income support to low- and medium-income households, so as to sustain demand, and offer transparent aid to businesses to ensure competitiveness. In addition, introduce a windfall tax on profits enjoyed by the fossil-fuel energy sector. The aim should be to ensure economies are ready to bounce back in the spring and growth can resume, rendering any worries over slightly increased public debt irrelevant.

The long-term goals should be clear to everyone, regardless of political position, who does not work in the fossil-fuel industry: invest in renewable-energy capacity, the energy efficiency of buildings and environmentally sustainable public-transport systems. Public finance will play a major role in this task, even if the financial ‘plumbing’ is more complicated—involving public development banks, public-private partnerships and so on.

But these measures will be difficult to implement if the alpha and omega of policy is instead to be the maintenance of central-bank ‘credibility’. Rather than accept its institutional shortcomings, the ECB is doubling down, reflecting the austerity bias inbuilt in the European Union since the Maastricht treaty.

The credibility of the bank could thereby be saved only at the expense of that of democratic political institutions—governments and parliaments. The current energy crisis is thus not just about inflation. It is about redesigning our governance institutions to ensure democratic accountability and a fair distribution of resources.

Andris Šuvajevs
Andris Šuvajevs

Andris Šuvajevs is a member of Latvia’s parliament, representing the Progressives, a green party of the left. His political work is focused on fiscal and tax policy as well as public spending. He has previously worked as a financial journalist, policy analyst and lecturer in social anthropology.

You are here: Home / Economy / Interest-rate rises versus the public interest

Most Popular Posts

Russia,information war Russia is winning the information warAiste Merfeldaite
Nanterre,police Nanterre and the suburbs: the lid comes offJoseph Downing
Russia,nuclear Russia’s dangerous nuclear consensusAna Palacio
Belarus,Lithuania A tale of two countries: Belarus and LithuaniaThorvaldur Gylfason and Eduard Hochreiter
retirement,Finland,ageing,pension,reform Late retirement: possible for many, not for allKati Kuitto

Most Recent Posts

Ukraine,fatigue Ukraine’s cause: momentum is diminishingStefan Wolff and Tetyana Malyarenko
Vienna,social housing Vienna social-housing model: celebrated but misusedGabu Heindl
social democracy,nation-state Social democracy versus the nativist rightJan Zielonka
chemical,European Union Which comes first—Big Toxics’ profits or health?Vicky Cann
Russia,journalists,Ukraine,target Ukraine: journalists in Russia’s sightsKelly Bjorkland and Simon Smith

Other Social Europe Publications

strategic autonomy Strategic autonomy
Bildschirmfoto 2023 05 08 um 21.36.25 scaled 1 RE No. 13: Failed Market Approaches to Long-Term Care
front cover Towards a social-democratic century?
Cover e1655225066994 National recovery and resilience plans
Untitled design The transatlantic relationship

ETUI advertisement

The future of remote work

The 12 chapters collected in this volume provide a multidisciplinary perspective on the impact and the future trajectories of remote work, from the nexus between the location from where work is performed and how it is performed to how remote locations may affect the way work is managed and organised, as well as the applicability of existing legislation. Additional questions concern remote work’s environmental and social impact and the rapidly changing nature of the relationship between work and life.


AVAILABLE HERE

Eurofound advertisement

Eurofound Talks: does Europe have the skills it needs for a changing economy?

In this episode of the Eurofound Talks podcast, Mary McCaughey speaks with Eurofound’s research manager, Tina Weber, its senior research manager, Gijs van Houten, and Giovanni Russo, senior expert at CEDEFOP (The European Centre for the Development of Vocational Training), about Europe’s skills challenges and what can be done to help workers and businesses adapt to future skills demands.

Listen where you get your podcasts, or for free, by clicking on the link below


LISTEN HERE

Foundation for European Progressive Studies Advertisement

The summer issue of the Progressive Post magazine by FEPS is out!

The Special Coverage of this new edition is dedicated to the importance of biodiversity, not only as a good in itself but also for the very existence of humankind. We need a paradigm change in the mostly utilitarian relation humans have with nature.

In this issue, we also look at the hazards of unregulated artificial intelligence, explore the shortcomings of the EU's approach to migration and asylum management, and analyse the social downside of the EU's current ethnically-focused Roma policy.


DOWNLOAD HERE

Hans Böckler Stiftung Advertisement

WSI European Collective Bargaining Report 2022 / 2023

With real wages falling by 4 per cent in 2022, workers in the European Union suffered an unprecedented loss in purchasing power. The reason for this was the rapid increase in consumer prices, behind which nominal wage growth fell significantly. Meanwhile, inflation is no longer driven by energy import prices, but by domestic factors. The increased profit margins of companies are a major reason for persistent inflation. In this difficult environment, trade unions are faced with the challenge of securing real wages—and companies have the responsibility of making their contribution to returning to the path of political stability by reducing excess profits.


DOWNLOAD HERE

About Social Europe

Our Mission

Article Submission

Membership

Advertisements

Legal Disclosure

Privacy Policy

Copyright

Social Europe ISSN 2628-7641

Social Europe Archives

Search Social Europe

Themes Archive

Politics Archive

Economy Archive

Society Archive

Ecology Archive

Follow us

RSS Feed

Follow us on Facebook

Follow us on Twitter

Follow us on LinkedIn

Follow us on YouTube